Working Paper |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
A Solution Concept for Majority Rule in Dynamic Settings |
0 |
0 |
0 |
19 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
159 |
A Tax-Based Test of the Dividend Signaling Hypothesis |
0 |
0 |
1 |
283 |
1 |
3 |
7 |
1,507 |
Addiction and Cue-Conditioned Cognitive Processes |
0 |
0 |
1 |
248 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
955 |
Addiction and Cue-Conditioned Cognitive Processes |
0 |
0 |
0 |
138 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
515 |
Behavioral Public Economics |
0 |
1 |
4 |
153 |
6 |
10 |
27 |
240 |
Behavioral Public Economics: Welfare and Policy Analysis with Non-Standard Decision-Makers |
0 |
0 |
0 |
535 |
1 |
4 |
10 |
1,566 |
Behavioral Public Economics: Welfare and Policy Analysis with Non-Standard Decision-Makers |
0 |
0 |
1 |
56 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
246 |
Behavioral Welfare Economics |
0 |
0 |
0 |
229 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
755 |
Bequests as Signals: An Explanation for the Equal Division Puzzle |
0 |
0 |
0 |
102 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
453 |
Bequests as a Means of Payment |
0 |
0 |
0 |
55 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
351 |
Beyond Revealed Preference Choice Theoretic Foundations for Behavioral Welfare Economics |
0 |
0 |
0 |
55 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
298 |
Beyond Revealed Preference: Choice Theoretic Foundations for Behavioral Welfare Economics |
0 |
0 |
2 |
269 |
1 |
3 |
8 |
826 |
Candidates, Character, and Corruption |
0 |
0 |
0 |
12 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
98 |
Causal Inference from Hypothetical Evaluations |
0 |
0 |
2 |
26 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
38 |
Comparable Worth in a General Equilibrium Model of the U.S. Economy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
70 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
390 |
Conspicuous Consumption, Pure Profits, and the Luxury Tax |
0 |
0 |
0 |
210 |
0 |
2 |
4 |
1,549 |
Democratic Policy Making with Real-Time Agenda Setting: Part 1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
172 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1,286 |
Dissaving After Retirement: Testing the Pure Life Cycle Hypothesis |
0 |
0 |
0 |
151 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
648 |
Do Consumers Exploit Precommitment Opportunities? Evidence from Natural Experiments Involving Liquor Consumption |
0 |
0 |
0 |
41 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
222 |
Do Estate and Gift Taxes Affect the Timing of Private Transfers? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
80 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
670 |
Do People Report Happiness Accurately? |
0 |
1 |
3 |
18 |
0 |
1 |
17 |
29 |
Do Real Estate Brokers Add Value When Listing Services Are Unbundled? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
120 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
563 |
Does the Estate Tax Raise Revenue? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
161 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
963 |
Education and Saving: The Long-Term Effects of High School Financial Curriculum Mandates |
0 |
0 |
1 |
365 |
0 |
1 |
7 |
2,319 |
Education and Saving: The Long-Term Effects of High School Financial Curriculum Mandates |
1 |
2 |
4 |
780 |
2 |
3 |
25 |
3,484 |
Evaluating Deliberative Competence: A Simple Method with an Application to Financial Choice |
0 |
0 |
0 |
110 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
297 |
Exclusive Dealing |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
416 |
Exclusive Dealing |
0 |
0 |
0 |
385 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1,627 |
Exclusive Dealing |
0 |
0 |
0 |
710 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
2,202 |
Financial Illiteracy, Education, and Retirement Saving |
0 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
3 |
4 |
16 |
5,130 |
Fiscal Policy With Impure Intergenerational Altruism |
0 |
0 |
0 |
49 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
290 |
Fiscal Policy with Impure Intergenerational Altruism (Reprint 011) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
250 |
How Do the Elderly Form Expectations? An Analysis of Responses to New Information |
0 |
0 |
0 |
90 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
449 |
How Much do Real Estate Brokers Add? A Case Study |
0 |
1 |
3 |
93 |
0 |
2 |
5 |
350 |
How Strong are Bequest Motives? Evidence Based on Estimates of the Demand for Life Insurance and Annuities |
0 |
0 |
1 |
179 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
649 |
How much should Americans be saving for retirement? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
506 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
2,622 |
Incomplete Contracts and Strategic Ambiguity |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
1,298 |
Intergenerational Altruism and Social Welfare: A Critique of the Dynastic Model |
0 |
0 |
0 |
98 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
431 |
Interpreting the Will of the People - A Positive Analysis of Ordinal Preference Aggregation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
32 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
22 |
Interpreting the Will of the People: A Positive Analysis of Ordinal Preference Aggregation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
12 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
18 |
Interventionist Preferences and the Welfare State: The Case of In-Kind Aid |
3 |
3 |
3 |
3 |
3 |
5 |
5 |
5 |
Is Everything Neutral? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
93 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
327 |
Life Cycle Annuity Valuation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
93 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
680 |
Neural Activity Reveals Preferences Without Choices |
0 |
0 |
0 |
123 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
269 |
Non-Choice Evaluations Predict Behavioral Responses to Changes in Economic Conditions |
0 |
0 |
1 |
57 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
179 |
Of Candidates and Character |
0 |
0 |
0 |
35 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
93 |
On the Potential of Neuroeconomics: A Critical (but Hopeful) Appraisal |
0 |
0 |
0 |
354 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
835 |
Optimal Default Options |
0 |
0 |
0 |
8 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
29 |
Optimal Money Burning |
0 |
0 |
0 |
135 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1,066 |
Optimal Money Burning: Theory and Application to Corporate Dividend Policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
463 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2,343 |
Peer Advice on Financial Decisions: A case of the blind leading the blind? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
30 |
0 |
2 |
9 |
87 |
Pension Funding and Saving |
0 |
0 |
0 |
100 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
619 |
Poverty and Self Control |
0 |
0 |
0 |
106 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
201 |
Poverty and Self-Control |
0 |
0 |
1 |
184 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
472 |
Predictability and Power in Legislative Bargaining |
0 |
0 |
0 |
25 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
86 |
Price Cutting and Business Stealing in Imperfect Cartels |
0 |
0 |
0 |
95 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
135 |
Private Saving and Public Policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
166 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
751 |
Private Saving and Public Policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
211 |
Projective Paternalism |
0 |
0 |
0 |
56 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
89 |
Projective Paternalism |
0 |
0 |
0 |
11 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
67 |
Rationalizable Strategic Behavior |
0 |
0 |
0 |
31 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
147 |
Rationalizable Strategic Behavior |
0 |
0 |
0 |
55 |
0 |
1 |
5 |
208 |
Rethinking Saving Incentives |
0 |
0 |
0 |
301 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
1,048 |
Ricardian Equivalence: An Evaluation of Theory and Evidence |
0 |
1 |
6 |
788 |
0 |
1 |
16 |
1,796 |
Saving and Life Insurance Holdings at Boston University – A Unique Case Study |
0 |
0 |
1 |
161 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
907 |
Social Image and the 50-50 Norm: A Theoretical and Experimental Analysis of Audience Effects |
0 |
0 |
1 |
66 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
348 |
Social Security Benefits: An Empirical Study of Expectations and Realizations |
0 |
0 |
0 |
92 |
0 |
2 |
6 |
545 |
Social preferences over ordinal outcomes |
0 |
0 |
2 |
44 |
1 |
1 |
9 |
48 |
Tax Policy and the Dividend Puzzle |
1 |
1 |
2 |
295 |
2 |
2 |
4 |
942 |
Taxation and Saving |
0 |
0 |
0 |
511 |
0 |
2 |
4 |
1,754 |
Taxation and Saving |
1 |
2 |
3 |
466 |
1 |
4 |
6 |
1,123 |
The Adequacy of Life Insurance: Evidence from the Health and Retirement Survey |
0 |
0 |
0 |
135 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
815 |
The Determinants and Consequences of Financial Education in the Workplace: Evidence from a Survey of Households |
0 |
0 |
1 |
212 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
859 |
The Determinants and Consequences of Financial Education in the Workplace: Evidence from a Survey of Households |
0 |
0 |
2 |
245 |
0 |
1 |
12 |
1,328 |
The Effects of Financial Education in the Workplace: Evidence from a Survey of Employers |
2 |
2 |
2 |
349 |
2 |
2 |
9 |
1,771 |
The Effects of Financial Education in the Workplace: Evidence from a Survey of Employers |
1 |
1 |
1 |
316 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
1,500 |
The Mismatch Between Life Insurance Holdings and Financial Vulnerabilities: Evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances |
0 |
0 |
0 |
126 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
534 |
The Strategic Bequest Motive |
0 |
0 |
4 |
63 |
0 |
3 |
9 |
333 |
The Timing of Retirement: A Comparison of Expectations and Realizations |
0 |
0 |
0 |
141 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
441 |
The Welfare Economics of Default Options in 401(k) Plans |
0 |
0 |
0 |
65 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
307 |
The adequacy of life insurance: evidence from the health and retirement survey |
0 |
0 |
0 |
156 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
784 |
The mismatch between life insurance holdings and financial vulnerabilities: evidence from the Health and Retirement Survey |
0 |
0 |
0 |
134 |
0 |
2 |
2 |
747 |
The mismatch between life insurance holdings and financial vulnerabilities: evidence from the Survey of Consumer Finances |
0 |
0 |
0 |
125 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
509 |
Understanding Conformity: An Experimental Investigation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
253 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
188 |
Welfare and the Act of Choosing |
0 |
0 |
1 |
24 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
23 |
What Accounts for the Variation in Retirement Wealth Among U.S. Households? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
350 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
1,749 |
What Accounts for the Variation in Retirement Wealth Among U.S. Households? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
260 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
1,860 |
When Fair Isn't Fair: Understanding Choice Reversals Involving Social Preferences |
0 |
0 |
1 |
75 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
102 |
Who Controls the Agenda Controls the Polity |
0 |
0 |
0 |
18 |
1 |
2 |
5 |
23 |
Total Working Papers |
9 |
15 |
61 |
14,614 |
30 |
79 |
400 |
67,464 |
Journal Article |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
100 Years of the American Economic Review: The Top 20 Articles |
1 |
1 |
6 |
795 |
2 |
4 |
26 |
1,974 |
A General Solution to the Problem of Setting Optimal Default Options |
0 |
0 |
2 |
10 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
22 |
A Neoclassical Perspective on Budget Deficits |
1 |
3 |
5 |
617 |
3 |
5 |
9 |
1,428 |
A Note on Dynamic Tax Incidence |
0 |
1 |
1 |
111 |
0 |
1 |
7 |
396 |
A Solution Concept for Majority Rule in Dynamic Settings |
0 |
0 |
2 |
49 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
291 |
A Tax-Based Test of the Dividend Signaling Hypothesis |
0 |
0 |
2 |
477 |
1 |
5 |
16 |
1,952 |
A Theory of Chosen Preferences |
1 |
1 |
11 |
71 |
2 |
3 |
22 |
254 |
A Theory of Conformity |
3 |
7 |
23 |
3,249 |
11 |
21 |
74 |
15,017 |
Addiction and Cue-Triggered Decision Processes |
0 |
1 |
2 |
162 |
0 |
3 |
7 |
682 |
Altruism within the Family Reconsidered: Do Nice Guys Finish Last? |
1 |
1 |
4 |
308 |
1 |
2 |
9 |
1,296 |
Are Life Insurance Holdings Related to Financial Vulnerabilities? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
51 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
353 |
Behavioral Welfare Economics |
0 |
0 |
4 |
249 |
0 |
4 |
14 |
819 |
Bequests as Signals: An Explanation for the Equal Division Puzzle |
0 |
1 |
1 |
132 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
631 |
Beyond Revealed Preference: Choice-Theoretic Foundations for Behavioral Welfare Economics |
0 |
2 |
14 |
215 |
0 |
6 |
35 |
657 |
Candidates, Character, and Corruption |
0 |
0 |
0 |
15 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
119 |
Coalition-Proof Nash Equilibria I. Concepts |
0 |
1 |
5 |
1,314 |
0 |
2 |
14 |
2,501 |
Coalition-Proof Nash Equilibria II. Applications |
0 |
0 |
1 |
182 |
1 |
2 |
5 |
338 |
Collective dynamic consistency in repeated games |
0 |
0 |
0 |
96 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
249 |
Common Agency |
0 |
0 |
18 |
706 |
0 |
1 |
28 |
1,760 |
Common Marketing Agency as a Device for Facilitating Collusion |
1 |
1 |
3 |
327 |
1 |
1 |
9 |
1,068 |
DO REAL ESTATE BROKERS ADD VALUE WHEN LISTING SERVICES ARE UNBUNDLED? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
18 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
183 |
Do Americans save too little? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
35 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
680 |
Do Consumers Exploit Commitment Opportunities? Evidence from Natural Experiments Involving Liquor Consumption |
0 |
0 |
1 |
32 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
134 |
Do estate and gift taxes affect the timing of private transfers? |
1 |
1 |
7 |
83 |
1 |
6 |
13 |
430 |
Economic Growth with Intergenerational Altruism |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
24 |
Education and saving:: The long-term effects of high school financial curriculum mandates |
2 |
2 |
32 |
992 |
11 |
24 |
123 |
3,139 |
Emmanuel Saez: 2009 John Bates Clark Medalist |
0 |
0 |
0 |
40 |
0 |
2 |
4 |
490 |
Evaluating Deliberative Competence: A Simple Method with an Application to Financial Choice |
0 |
0 |
1 |
14 |
0 |
2 |
10 |
61 |
Exclusive Dealing |
2 |
4 |
9 |
382 |
7 |
12 |
22 |
1,133 |
Fiscal Policy with Impure Intergenerational Altruism |
0 |
0 |
1 |
72 |
1 |
1 |
5 |
558 |
Fiscalité et coût du capital: une comparaison internationale |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
11 |
How Much Should Americans Be Saving for Retirement? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
209 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
1,128 |
How Strong Are Bequest Motives? Evidence Based on Estimates of the Demand for Life Insurance and Annuities |
0 |
1 |
9 |
330 |
2 |
6 |
26 |
1,113 |
In defense of behavioral welfare economics |
0 |
2 |
15 |
50 |
2 |
4 |
31 |
98 |
Incomplete Contracts and Strategic Ambiguity |
0 |
0 |
1 |
628 |
3 |
4 |
15 |
1,931 |
Intergenerational Altruism, Dynastic Equilibria and Social Welfare |
0 |
0 |
0 |
67 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
287 |
Is Everything Neutral? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
281 |
1 |
1 |
10 |
1,068 |
Markov perfect equilibria in altruistic growth economies with production uncertainty |
0 |
0 |
0 |
34 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
108 |
Memory and Anticipation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
98 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
355 |
Menu Auctions, Resource Allocation, and Economic Influence |
0 |
2 |
11 |
1,279 |
2 |
6 |
30 |
2,793 |
Multimarket Contact and Collusive Behavior |
3 |
4 |
19 |
1,818 |
9 |
18 |
54 |
5,529 |
Neural Activity Reveals Preferences without Choices |
0 |
0 |
1 |
47 |
0 |
2 |
5 |
210 |
On the Existence of Markov-Consistent Plans under Production Uncertainty |
0 |
0 |
0 |
14 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
101 |
On the Potential of Neuroeconomics: A Critical (but Hopeful) Appraisal |
0 |
0 |
1 |
138 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
476 |
On the Voluntary and Involuntary Provision of Public Goods |
0 |
0 |
3 |
401 |
2 |
2 |
7 |
912 |
Optimal Fiscal and Monetary Policy: Some Recent Results |
0 |
0 |
0 |
35 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
399 |
Optimal Money Burning: Theory and Application to Corporate Dividends |
0 |
0 |
0 |
80 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
452 |
Peer Advice on Financial Decisions: A Case of the Blind Leading the Blind? |
0 |
1 |
4 |
4 |
1 |
9 |
16 |
16 |
Poverty and Self‐Control |
0 |
1 |
4 |
85 |
0 |
2 |
8 |
352 |
Predictability and Power in Legislative Bargaining |
0 |
0 |
1 |
7 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
69 |
Price Cutting and Business Stealing in Imperfect Cartels |
0 |
0 |
0 |
27 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
172 |
Rational Strategic Choice Revisited |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
Rationalizable Strategic Behavior |
0 |
1 |
5 |
598 |
1 |
4 |
19 |
1,577 |
Repeated Games with Asymptotically Finite Horizons |
1 |
1 |
2 |
64 |
1 |
2 |
5 |
142 |
Robustness of Rank Independence in Risky Choice |
0 |
0 |
1 |
25 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
64 |
Saving and Life Insurance Holdings at Boston University – a Unique Case Study |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
42 |
Social Image and the 50-50 Norm: A Theoretical and Experimental Analysis of Audience Effects |
0 |
1 |
2 |
144 |
1 |
4 |
15 |
667 |
Social Security and Personal Saving: An Analysis of Expectations |
0 |
0 |
1 |
72 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
249 |
Strategic Deterrence of Sequential Entry into an Industry |
1 |
2 |
2 |
171 |
2 |
3 |
5 |
490 |
THE EFFECTS OF FINANCIAL EDUCATION IN THE WORKPLACE: EVIDENCE FROM A SURVEY OF EMPLOYERS |
0 |
0 |
1 |
100 |
1 |
2 |
9 |
459 |
Tax Policy and the Dividend Puzzle |
0 |
0 |
1 |
367 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
1,826 |
The Good, the Bad, and the Ugly: A Unified Approach to Behavioral Welfare Economics1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
58 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
128 |
The Mismatch Between Life Insurance Holdings and Financial Vulnerabilities: Evidence from the Health and Retirement Study |
0 |
0 |
1 |
79 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
442 |
The Power of the Last Word in Legislative Policy Making |
0 |
0 |
3 |
96 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
314 |
The Strategic Bequest Motive |
0 |
1 |
4 |
842 |
2 |
9 |
23 |
2,837 |
The Strategic Bequest Motive |
0 |
0 |
2 |
353 |
0 |
2 |
10 |
1,636 |
The Welfare Economics of Default Options in 401(k) Plans |
0 |
1 |
1 |
38 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
234 |
The economic effects of social security: Toward a reconciliation of theory and measurement |
0 |
0 |
0 |
225 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
699 |
The effects of financial education in the workplace: evidence from a survey of households |
2 |
6 |
22 |
633 |
3 |
12 |
69 |
1,748 |
Toward Choice-Theoretic Foundations for Behavioral Welfare Economics |
0 |
0 |
1 |
76 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
254 |
Veblen Effects in a Theory of Conspicuous Consumption |
1 |
3 |
13 |
1,778 |
8 |
19 |
72 |
8,198 |
What Accounts for the Variation in Retirement Wealth among U.S. Households? |
0 |
0 |
3 |
345 |
0 |
1 |
10 |
1,258 |
What Motivates Paternalism? An Experimental Study |
1 |
2 |
5 |
75 |
2 |
4 |
15 |
261 |
When Fair Isn’t Fair: Understanding Choice Reversals Involving Social Preferences |
1 |
1 |
5 |
22 |
3 |
4 |
16 |
154 |
Who Controls the Agenda Controls the Legislature |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
0 |
0 |
8 |
35 |
Total Journal Articles |
23 |
57 |
300 |
22,620 |
91 |
240 |
1,023 |
79,939 |