Journal Article |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
A Theory of Rationing by Waiting |
0 |
0 |
6 |
52 |
0 |
1 |
8 |
586 |
An Alternative Approach to the Analysis of Taxation |
0 |
0 |
7 |
153 |
0 |
0 |
12 |
437 |
An Economic Analysis of Slavery |
1 |
1 |
1 |
111 |
1 |
4 |
8 |
1,436 |
Assets, Subsistence, and The Supply Curve of Labor |
0 |
0 |
4 |
60 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
262 |
Celebrating Fifty Years to Cheung's Theory of Share Tenancy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
34 |
Competitive Tying Arrangements: The Case of Medical Insurance |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
136 |
Confiscation by the Ruler: The Rise and Fall of Jewish Lending in the Middle Ages |
0 |
0 |
0 |
17 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
221 |
Discussion of Innovation Papers |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
76 |
Excess Capacity in Monopolistic Competition |
0 |
0 |
2 |
180 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
1,202 |
Investment, Scale, and Growth |
0 |
0 |
1 |
31 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
189 |
Is the act of voting rational? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
34 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
79 |
Knight's 'Moral Hazard' Theory of Organization |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
308 |
Measurement Cost and the Organization of Markets |
0 |
0 |
1 |
103 |
1 |
3 |
10 |
1,275 |
Organizational Forms and Measurement Costs |
0 |
2 |
4 |
33 |
0 |
3 |
7 |
471 |
Parliament as a wealth-maximizing institution: The right to the residual and the right to vote |
0 |
0 |
0 |
23 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
92 |
Prevention Is Better than Cure: The Role of IPO Syndicates in Precluding Information Acquisition |
0 |
0 |
0 |
51 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
345 |
Private Schools and Public School Finance |
0 |
0 |
0 |
80 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
293 |
Productivity and the Price of Medical Services |
0 |
0 |
0 |
61 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
385 |
Property rights and the evolution of the state |
0 |
0 |
0 |
158 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
930 |
Some Fallacies in the Interpretation of Information Costs |
1 |
3 |
6 |
27 |
1 |
3 |
9 |
248 |
Standards and the Form of Agreement |
0 |
0 |
1 |
83 |
0 |
2 |
3 |
436 |
Steve Cheung in Seattle, 1969–1982 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
26 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
68 |
Taxation and Voting Rights in Medieval England and France |
0 |
0 |
1 |
9 |
2 |
2 |
8 |
32 |
The Allocation of Resources by Voting |
0 |
0 |
0 |
104 |
1 |
3 |
5 |
350 |
The Demand Curves for Giffen Goods Are Downward Sloping |
0 |
0 |
0 |
372 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
3,041 |
The Determination of Daily Hours and Wages |
0 |
1 |
5 |
190 |
2 |
4 |
12 |
620 |
The Development and Decline of Medieval Voting Institutions: A Comparison of England and France |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
354 |
The Effect of the Utilization Rate on the Division of Labor |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
147 |
The Entrepreneur's Reward for Self-policing |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
395 |
The Evolution of Criminal Law and Police during the Pre-modern Era |
0 |
0 |
5 |
21 |
0 |
1 |
12 |
166 |
The Market for a Semipublic Good: The Case of the American Economic Review |
0 |
0 |
1 |
34 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
231 |
The Origins of Democracy in England |
1 |
3 |
9 |
34 |
1 |
7 |
19 |
72 |
The Production Function and Technical Change in the Steam-Power Industry |
0 |
0 |
2 |
16 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
85 |
The Role of Contract in Quality Assurance |
0 |
0 |
3 |
43 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
159 |
The capture of wealth by monopolists and the protection of property rights |
1 |
1 |
3 |
207 |
2 |
6 |
14 |
635 |
The rate of technical progress: The "indianapolis 500" |
0 |
0 |
0 |
31 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
102 |
Two propositions on the optimum level of producing collective goods |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
33 |
Voting behavior, efficiency, and equity |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
15 |
What are ‘property rights’, and why do they matter? A comment on Hodgson's article |
0 |
0 |
4 |
32 |
0 |
0 |
8 |
70 |
Total Journal Articles |
4 |
11 |
67 |
2,395 |
12 |
47 |
182 |
16,016 |