Working Paper |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
A General-Equilibrium Asset-Pricing Approach to the Measurement of Nominal and Real Bank Output |
0 |
0 |
0 |
83 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
324 |
A Theory of the Reform of Bureaucratic Institutions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
421 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
3,219 |
A general-equilibrium asset-pricing approach to the measurement of nominal and real bank output |
0 |
0 |
0 |
155 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
728 |
Aggregate Productivity and the Productivity of Aggregates |
0 |
0 |
1 |
262 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
1,025 |
Aggregate productivity and aggregate technology |
1 |
1 |
2 |
593 |
1 |
3 |
7 |
1,479 |
Aggregate productivity and the productivity of aggregates |
0 |
0 |
0 |
93 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
531 |
Allocative and Remitted Wages: New Facts and Challenges for Keynesian Models |
0 |
0 |
0 |
150 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
269 |
Appropriate Technology and Growth |
0 |
0 |
1 |
774 |
1 |
1 |
5 |
1,947 |
Are Apparent Productive Spillovers a Figment of Specification Error |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
344 |
Are Apparent Productive Spillovers a Figment of Specification Error? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
137 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
670 |
Are Price-Cost Markups Rising in the United States? A Discussion of the Evidence |
0 |
1 |
4 |
88 |
1 |
3 |
7 |
217 |
Are Technology Improvements Contractionary? |
1 |
1 |
5 |
766 |
1 |
3 |
18 |
2,789 |
Are Technology Improvements Contractionary? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
98 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
644 |
Are apparent productive spillovers a figment of specification error? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
41 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
353 |
Are technology improvements contractionary? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
606 |
0 |
1 |
8 |
2,245 |
Are technology improvements contractionary? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
238 |
1 |
1 |
5 |
865 |
Business Cycles in International Historical Perspective |
0 |
0 |
1 |
916 |
1 |
3 |
8 |
2,507 |
Constant Returns and Small Markups in U.S. Manufacturing |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
384 |
Constant returns and small markups in U.S. manufacturing |
0 |
0 |
0 |
98 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
490 |
Contractionary technology improvements in multi-sector DSGE models |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
118 |
Corruption and Reform |
0 |
0 |
1 |
318 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
1,063 |
Corruption in Transition |
0 |
0 |
1 |
541 |
0 |
2 |
5 |
1,261 |
Cyclical Productivity with Unobserved Input Variation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
615 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
2,171 |
Endogenous Volatility at the Zero Lower Bound: Implications for Stabilization Policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
40 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
72 |
Endogenous volatility at the zero lower bound: implications for stabilization policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
70 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
139 |
Estimating the Cyclicality of Marginal Costs Directly |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
284 |
Information and communications technology as a general-purpose technology: evidence from U.S industry data |
0 |
0 |
0 |
302 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
1,432 |
Intermediate Goods and Business Cycles: Implications for Productivity and Welfare |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
545 |
Intermediate Goods and Business Cycles: Implications for Productivity and Welfare |
0 |
0 |
0 |
223 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
901 |
New Evidence on Durable Goods Biased Technological Change |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
403 |
Optimal Advice for Monetary Policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
47 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
288 |
Procyclical Productivity: Increasing Returns or Cyclical Utilization? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
188 |
1 |
3 |
3 |
715 |
Procyclical Productivity: Overhead Inputs or Cyclical Utilization |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
278 |
Productivity Growth in the 1990s: Technology, Utilization, or Adjustment? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
389 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
1,416 |
Productivity and the Welfare of Nations |
0 |
1 |
1 |
37 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
157 |
Productivity and the Welfare of Nations |
0 |
0 |
0 |
30 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
144 |
Productivity and the Welfare of Nations |
0 |
0 |
1 |
26 |
1 |
2 |
4 |
105 |
Productivity and the Welfare of Nations |
0 |
1 |
1 |
62 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
87 |
Productivity and the Welfare of Nations |
0 |
0 |
1 |
214 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
761 |
Productivity and the welfare of nations |
0 |
0 |
1 |
60 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
159 |
Productivity and the welfare of nations |
0 |
0 |
0 |
38 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
128 |
Productivity growth in the 1990s: technology, utilization, or adjustment |
0 |
0 |
0 |
355 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
1,571 |
Productivity, Welfare and Reallocation: Theory and Firm Level Evidence |
0 |
0 |
0 |
157 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
394 |
Productivity, Welfare and Reallocation: Theory and Firm-Level Evidence |
0 |
0 |
0 |
37 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
146 |
Productivity, Welfare and Reallocation: Theory and Firm-Level Evidence |
0 |
0 |
0 |
51 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
177 |
Productivity, welfare and reallocation: theory and firm-level evidence |
0 |
0 |
0 |
80 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
227 |
Productivity, welfare, and reallocation: theory and firm-level evidence |
0 |
1 |
1 |
24 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
139 |
Returns to scale in U.S. production: estimates and implications |
0 |
0 |
1 |
815 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
1,967 |
Risk Bearing, Implicit Financial Services and Specialization in the Financial Industry |
0 |
0 |
0 |
34 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
184 |
Risk bearing, implicit financial services, and specialization in the financial industry |
0 |
0 |
0 |
101 |
0 |
0 |
8 |
587 |
Risky Business Cycles |
1 |
1 |
4 |
27 |
1 |
1 |
8 |
57 |
Risky Business Cycles |
0 |
1 |
3 |
75 |
3 |
4 |
12 |
145 |
Should Central Banks Target Investment Prices? |
0 |
0 |
5 |
184 |
2 |
4 |
13 |
338 |
Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Wages |
0 |
1 |
1 |
79 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
221 |
Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Wages |
0 |
0 |
0 |
45 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
180 |
Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Wages |
0 |
1 |
1 |
89 |
0 |
1 |
5 |
341 |
Some evidence on the importance of sticky wages |
0 |
0 |
0 |
48 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
185 |
Technological progress, the \"user cost of money,\" and the real output of banks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
27 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
98 |
Technology Shocks in a Two-Sector DSGE Model |
3 |
5 |
20 |
547 |
5 |
8 |
34 |
1,113 |
The Case of the Missing Productivity Growth: Or, Does Information Technology Explain why Productivity Accelerated in the US but not the UK? |
0 |
1 |
1 |
374 |
1 |
3 |
6 |
1,121 |
The Case of the Missing Productivity Growth: Or, Does Information technology explain why productivity accelerated in the United States but not the United Kingdom? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
172 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
571 |
The Value of Risk: Measuring the Service Output of U.S. Commercial Banks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
87 |
2 |
2 |
4 |
297 |
The Value of Risk: Measuring the Service Output of U.S. Commercial Banks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
47 |
The case of the missing productivity growth: or, does information technology explain why productivity accelerated in the United States but not the United Kingdom? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
519 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
1,443 |
The value of risk: measuring the service output of U. S. commercial banks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
162 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
387 |
Uncertainty Shocks in a Model of Effective Demand |
0 |
0 |
3 |
133 |
4 |
6 |
16 |
471 |
Uncertainty Shocks in a Model of Effective Demand |
0 |
1 |
1 |
337 |
1 |
5 |
9 |
801 |
Uncertainty Shocks in a Model of Effective Demand: Reply |
0 |
0 |
0 |
38 |
0 |
1 |
5 |
82 |
Uncertainty shocks in a model of effective demand |
0 |
0 |
0 |
75 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
298 |
Uncertainty shocks in a model of effective demand |
0 |
0 |
1 |
134 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
324 |
What do we know and not know about potential output? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
311 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
654 |
Whither News Shocks? |
0 |
0 |
5 |
100 |
0 |
2 |
11 |
232 |
Why Is Productivity Procyclical? Why Do We Care? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
282 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
1,059 |
Why is productivity procyclical? Why do we care? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
390 |
0 |
2 |
2 |
1,175 |
Why is productivity procyclical? Why do we care? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
181 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
618 |
Total Working Papers |
6 |
17 |
70 |
14,798 |
38 |
84 |
294 |
51,307 |