Working Paper |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
A General-Equilibrium Asset-Pricing Approach to the Measurement of Nominal and Real Bank Output |
0 |
0 |
0 |
83 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
323 |
A Theory of the Reform of Bureaucratic Institutions |
0 |
0 |
1 |
421 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
3,218 |
A general-equilibrium asset-pricing approach to the measurement of nominal and real bank output |
0 |
0 |
0 |
155 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
726 |
Aggregate Productivity and the Productivity of Aggregates |
0 |
0 |
1 |
261 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1,022 |
Aggregate productivity and aggregate technology |
0 |
0 |
1 |
591 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
1,473 |
Aggregate productivity and the productivity of aggregates |
0 |
0 |
0 |
93 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
529 |
Allocative and Remitted Wages: New Facts and Challenges for Keynesian Models |
0 |
0 |
0 |
150 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
267 |
Appropriate Technology and Growth |
0 |
0 |
1 |
774 |
1 |
1 |
7 |
1,946 |
Are Apparent Productive Spillovers a Figment of Specification Error |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
344 |
Are Apparent Productive Spillovers a Figment of Specification Error? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
137 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
670 |
Are Price-Cost Markups Rising in the United States? A Discussion of the Evidence |
0 |
2 |
4 |
86 |
0 |
2 |
9 |
212 |
Are Technology Improvements Contractionary? |
0 |
2 |
6 |
763 |
0 |
4 |
20 |
2,779 |
Are Technology Improvements Contractionary? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
98 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
644 |
Are apparent productive spillovers a figment of specification error? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
41 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
353 |
Are technology improvements contractionary? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
606 |
1 |
1 |
5 |
2,240 |
Are technology improvements contractionary? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
237 |
0 |
2 |
5 |
863 |
Business Cycles in International Historical Perspective |
0 |
0 |
3 |
916 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
2,502 |
Constant Returns and Small Markups in U.S. Manufacturing |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
383 |
Constant returns and small markups in U.S. manufacturing |
0 |
0 |
0 |
98 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
490 |
Contractionary technology improvements in multi-sector DSGE models |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
117 |
Corruption and Reform |
0 |
0 |
0 |
317 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1,061 |
Corruption in Transition |
0 |
0 |
0 |
540 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
1,258 |
Cyclical Productivity with Unobserved Input Variation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
615 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
2,168 |
Endogenous Volatility at the Zero Lower Bound: Implications for Stabilization Policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
40 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
71 |
Endogenous volatility at the zero lower bound: implications for stabilization policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
70 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
138 |
Estimating the Cyclicality of Marginal Costs Directly |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
284 |
Information and communications technology as a general-purpose technology: evidence from U.S industry data |
0 |
0 |
0 |
302 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
1,430 |
Intermediate Goods and Business Cycles: Implications for Productivity and Welfare |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
544 |
Intermediate Goods and Business Cycles: Implications for Productivity and Welfare |
0 |
0 |
0 |
223 |
0 |
1 |
9 |
901 |
New Evidence on Durable Goods Biased Technological Change |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
403 |
Optimal Advice for Monetary Policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
47 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
287 |
Procyclical Productivity: Increasing Returns or Cyclical Utilization? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
188 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
712 |
Procyclical Productivity: Overhead Inputs or Cyclical Utilization |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
278 |
Productivity Growth in the 1990s: Technology, Utilization, or Adjustment? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
389 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
1,415 |
Productivity and the Welfare of Nations |
0 |
0 |
0 |
25 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
101 |
Productivity and the Welfare of Nations |
0 |
0 |
0 |
61 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
85 |
Productivity and the Welfare of Nations |
0 |
0 |
1 |
30 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
141 |
Productivity and the Welfare of Nations |
0 |
0 |
0 |
36 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
155 |
Productivity and the Welfare of Nations |
0 |
0 |
1 |
213 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
757 |
Productivity and the welfare of nations |
0 |
0 |
0 |
38 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
127 |
Productivity and the welfare of nations |
0 |
0 |
0 |
59 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
156 |
Productivity growth in the 1990s: technology, utilization, or adjustment |
0 |
0 |
0 |
355 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
1,569 |
Productivity, Welfare and Reallocation: Theory and Firm Level Evidence |
0 |
0 |
0 |
157 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
393 |
Productivity, Welfare and Reallocation: Theory and Firm-Level Evidence |
0 |
0 |
0 |
37 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
146 |
Productivity, Welfare and Reallocation: Theory and Firm-Level Evidence |
0 |
0 |
0 |
51 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
177 |
Productivity, welfare and reallocation: theory and firm-level evidence |
0 |
0 |
0 |
80 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
227 |
Productivity, welfare, and reallocation: theory and firm-level evidence |
0 |
0 |
1 |
23 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
138 |
Returns to scale in U.S. production: estimates and implications |
0 |
0 |
1 |
815 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
1,966 |
Risk Bearing, Implicit Financial Services and Specialization in the Financial Industry |
0 |
0 |
0 |
34 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
184 |
Risk bearing, implicit financial services, and specialization in the financial industry |
0 |
0 |
0 |
101 |
7 |
8 |
8 |
587 |
Risky Business Cycles |
0 |
1 |
3 |
26 |
1 |
2 |
9 |
55 |
Risky Business Cycles |
0 |
1 |
3 |
73 |
1 |
3 |
16 |
139 |
Should Central Banks Target Investment Prices? |
0 |
2 |
6 |
183 |
1 |
5 |
15 |
333 |
Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Wages |
0 |
0 |
0 |
45 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
180 |
Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Wages |
0 |
0 |
0 |
78 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
220 |
Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Wages |
0 |
0 |
0 |
88 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
339 |
Some evidence on the importance of sticky wages |
0 |
0 |
0 |
48 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
184 |
Technological progress, the \"user cost of money,\" and the real output of banks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
27 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
98 |
Technology Shocks in a Two-Sector DSGE Model |
1 |
5 |
24 |
538 |
2 |
6 |
50 |
1,097 |
The Case of the Missing Productivity Growth: Or, Does Information Technology Explain why Productivity Accelerated in the US but not the UK? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
373 |
1 |
1 |
6 |
1,118 |
The Case of the Missing Productivity Growth: Or, Does Information technology explain why productivity accelerated in the United States but not the United Kingdom? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
172 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
571 |
The Value of Risk: Measuring the Service Output of U.S. Commercial Banks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
87 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
295 |
The Value of Risk: Measuring the Service Output of U.S. Commercial Banks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
46 |
The case of the missing productivity growth: or, does information technology explain why productivity accelerated in the United States but not the United Kingdom? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
519 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1,441 |
The value of risk: measuring the service output of U. S. commercial banks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
162 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
387 |
Uncertainty Shocks in a Model of Effective Demand |
0 |
0 |
5 |
132 |
1 |
2 |
23 |
463 |
Uncertainty Shocks in a Model of Effective Demand |
0 |
0 |
2 |
336 |
0 |
1 |
7 |
793 |
Uncertainty Shocks in a Model of Effective Demand: Reply |
0 |
0 |
1 |
38 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
79 |
Uncertainty shocks in a model of effective demand |
0 |
0 |
0 |
75 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
297 |
Uncertainty shocks in a model of effective demand |
0 |
1 |
1 |
134 |
0 |
2 |
4 |
322 |
What do we know and not know about potential output? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
310 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
653 |
Whither News Shocks? |
0 |
1 |
5 |
100 |
1 |
2 |
11 |
230 |
Why Is Productivity Procyclical? Why Do We Care? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
282 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1,058 |
Why is productivity procyclical? Why do we care? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
181 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
616 |
Why is productivity procyclical? Why do we care? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
390 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1,173 |
Total Working Papers |
1 |
15 |
71 |
14,762 |
25 |
62 |
308 |
51,147 |