Working Paper |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
A Dynamic Efficiency Rationale for Public Investment in the Health of the Young |
0 |
0 |
0 |
32 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
81 |
A Dynamic Efficiency Rationale for Public Investment in the Health of the Young |
0 |
0 |
0 |
24 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
88 |
A Positive Theory of the Income Redistributive Focus of Social Security |
0 |
0 |
0 |
60 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
324 |
A Rational-Choice Model of Covid-19 Transmission with Endogenous Quarantining and Two-sided Prevention |
0 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
19 |
A dynamic efficiency rationale for public investment in the health of the young |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
A dynamic-efficiency rationale for public investment in the health of the young |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
A positive theory of the income redistributive focus of social security |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
A rational-choice model of Covid-19 transmission with endogenous quarantining and two-sided prevention |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
14 |
A way to resolve intergenerational conflict over the environment under the Pareto criterion using green bonds |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
17 |
Age-Specific Employment Policies |
0 |
0 |
1 |
115 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
580 |
Age-specific employment policies |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
Aging, Unemployment, and Welfare in a Life-Cycle Model with Costly Labor Market Search |
0 |
0 |
0 |
160 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
487 |
Aging, unemployment, and welfare in a life-cycle model with costly labor market search |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
Are the Joneses Making You Financially Vulnerable? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
40 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
161 |
Can Financial Intermediation Induce Endogenous Fluctuations? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
189 |
Can financial intermediation induce endogenous fluctuations |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Can optimal unfunded public pensions co-exist with voluntary private retirement savings? |
10 |
10 |
10 |
10 |
8 |
10 |
10 |
10 |
Central bank responsibility, seigniorage, and welfare |
0 |
0 |
0 |
267 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
938 |
Chaotic Planning Solutions in the Textbook Model of Labor Market Search and Matching |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
Chaotic Planning Solutions in the Textbook Model of Labor Market Search and Matching |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
40 |
Child Survival and Contraception Choice: Theory and Evidence |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
Choosing to Keep Up with the Joneses and Income Inequality |
0 |
0 |
1 |
109 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
491 |
Choosing to keep up with the Joneses |
0 |
0 |
0 |
66 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
265 |
Choosing to keep up with the Joneses and income inequality |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
0 |
2 |
6 |
7 |
Choosing to keep up with the Joneses and income inequality |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
7 |
Contraception and the Demographic Transition |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
Contraception and the Fertility Transition |
0 |
0 |
1 |
80 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
141 |
Contraception and the Fertility Transition |
0 |
0 |
0 |
24 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
67 |
Contraception and the fertility transition |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
Credit Market Imperfections, Income Distribution, and Capital Accumulation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
256 |
Credit Markets with time-inconsistent agents and strategic loan default |
2 |
7 |
15 |
48 |
6 |
14 |
34 |
89 |
Deviant Generations, Ricardian Equivalence, and Growth Cycles |
0 |
0 |
0 |
70 |
0 |
1 |
5 |
397 |
Deviant generations, Ricardian equivalence, and growth cycles |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
Do Workers Discriminate against Their Out-group Employers? Evidence from the Gig Economy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
17 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
110 |
Do the Joneses make you financially vulnerable? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
Do the Joneses make you financially vulnerable? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
45 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
92 |
Do workers discriminate against their out-group employers? Evidence from the gig economy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
18 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
34 |
Dynamics of the Planning Solution in the Discrete-Time Textbook Model of Labor Market Search and Matching |
0 |
0 |
0 |
35 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
276 |
Dynamics of the Planning Solution in the Textbook Model of Labor Market Search and Matching |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
Dynamics of the planning solution in the discrete-time textbook model of labor market search and matching |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
Endogenous Borrowing Constraints and Wealth Inequality |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
15 |
Endogenous borrowing constraints and wealth inequality |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
5 |
Endogenous borrowing constraints and wealth inequality |
1 |
1 |
3 |
93 |
1 |
3 |
8 |
145 |
Exponential-Growth Prediction Bias and Compliance with Safety Measures in the Times of COVID-19 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
42 |
Exponential-growth prediction bias and compliance with safety measures in the times of COVID-19 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
32 |
Exponential-growth prediction bias and compliance with safety measures related to COVID-19 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
13 |
Fertility Choice Under Child Mortality and Social Norms |
0 |
0 |
1 |
26 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
107 |
Fertility choice under child mortality and social norms |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
9 |
Fertility choice under child mortality and social norms |
0 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
9 |
Heterogeneity, Redistribution, and the Friedman Rule |
0 |
0 |
0 |
36 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
451 |
Heterogeneity, redistribution, and the Friedman rule |
0 |
0 |
0 |
112 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
363 |
Heterogeneity, redistribution, and the Friedman rule |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
8 |
Heterogeneity, redistribution, and the Friedman rule |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
Intergenerational Debt Dynamics Without Tears |
0 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
Intergenerational debt dynamics without tears |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
12 |
Is Income Inequality Linked to Infectious Disease Prevalence? A Hypothesis-Generating Ecological Study Using Tuberculosis |
0 |
0 |
1 |
18 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
18 |
Is Reserve Ratio Arithmetic More Pleasant? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
366 |
Is Reserve-ratio Arithmetic More Pleasant? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
Labor Market Search and Optimal Retirement Policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
89 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
455 |
Labor Market Search and Optimal Retirement Policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
25 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
264 |
Labor Market Search and Optimal Retirement Policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
Labor market search and optimal retirement policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
Minimum Consumption Requirements and Cycles in an Overlapping Generations Model of Money |
0 |
0 |
0 |
49 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
167 |
Minimum consumption requirements and cycles in an overlapping generations model of money [Resurrecting Equilibria Through Cycles] |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Monetary Policy And The Distribution Of Income |
0 |
0 |
0 |
389 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1,087 |
Monetary Policy Arithmetic: Some Recent Contributions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
Monetary Policy Arithmetic: Some Recent Contributions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
210 |
Monetary Policy, Fiscal Policy, and the Inflation Tax: Equivalence Results |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
727 |
Monetary Policy, Fiscal Policy, and the Inflation Tax: Equivalence Results |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
Monetary policy and the distribution of income |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
Monetary, Fiscal, and Bank Regulatory Policy in a Simple Monetary Growth Model |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
387 |
Monetary, Fiscal, and Bank Regulatory Policy in a Simple Monetary Growth Model |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
488 |
Money, output and the payment system: Optimal monetary policy in a model with hidden effort |
0 |
0 |
0 |
93 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
294 |
On Myopia As Rationale for Social Security |
0 |
0 |
0 |
40 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
237 |
On Myopia as Rationale for Social Security |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
On Myopia as Rationale for Social Security |
0 |
0 |
0 |
64 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
232 |
On the Commitment Needs of Partially Naive Agents |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
On the Commitment Needs of Partially Naive Agents |
0 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
14 |
On the Use of the Inflation Tax When Nondistortionary Taxes Are Available |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
On the Use of the Inflation Tax when Non-Distortionary Taxes Are Available |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
267 |
On the Use of the Inflation Tax when Non-Distortionary Taxes are Available |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
On the Usefulness of the Constrained Planning Problem in a Model of Money |
0 |
0 |
0 |
15 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
147 |
On the usefulness of the constrained planning problem in a model of money |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
On the usefulness of the constrained planning problem in a model of money |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
Optimal Choice of Monetary Instruments in an Economy with Real and Liquidity Shocks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
129 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
545 |
Optimal Health and Environmental Policies in a Pollution-Growth Nexus |
0 |
0 |
0 |
58 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
112 |
Optimal Monetary Policy Rules Under Persistent Shocks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
65 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
202 |
Optimal Monetary Policy and Economic Growth |
0 |
0 |
0 |
240 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
522 |
Optimal Monetary and Exchange Rate Policies in Crisis-Prone Small Open Economies |
0 |
0 |
0 |
42 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
146 |
Optimal choice of monetary instruments in an economy with real and liquidity shocks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
Optimal choice of monetary policy instruments in an economy with real and liquidity shocks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
Optimal health and environmental policies in a pollution-growth nexus |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
Optimal health and environmental policies in a pollution-growth nexus |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
Optimal monetary policy and economic growth |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
11 |
35 |
Optimal monetary policy and economic growth |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
11 |
Optimal monetary policy rules under persistent shocks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
Optimal monetary rules under persistent shocks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
PRIVATE VERSUS PUBLIC OLD-AGE SECURITY |
0 |
0 |
0 |
34 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
68 |
Pareto-improving transition to fully funded pensions under myopia |
0 |
0 |
1 |
8 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
22 |
Pareto-improving transition to fully funded pensions under myopia |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
12 |
Pareto-improving transition to fully funded pensions under myopia |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
21 |
Patience Cycles |
0 |
0 |
2 |
74 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
64 |
Patience Cycles |
0 |
0 |
0 |
43 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
106 |
Patience Cycles |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
5 |
Patience cycles |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
Pension reform and wealth inequality: Theory and evidence |
9 |
9 |
9 |
9 |
6 |
6 |
6 |
6 |
Pension reform and wealth inequality: evidence from Denmark |
0 |
0 |
3 |
8 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
14 |
Pension reform and wealth inequality: evidence from Denmark |
0 |
0 |
4 |
33 |
1 |
1 |
9 |
55 |
Price Level Volatility: A Simple Model of Money Taxes and Sunspots |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
270 |
Private versus Public Old-Age Security |
0 |
0 |
0 |
18 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
92 |
Private versus public old-age security |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
11 |
Private versus public old-age security |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
Private versus public old-age security |
0 |
0 |
0 |
18 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
92 |
Public and Private Expenditures on Health in a Growth Model |
0 |
0 |
1 |
181 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
538 |
Public and private expenditures on health in a growth model |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
Public and private expenditures on health in a growth model |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
Reference-Dependent Preferences, Time Inconsistency, and Unfunded Pensions |
0 |
0 |
1 |
20 |
1 |
1 |
6 |
66 |
Reference-dependent preferences, time inconsistency, and pay-as-you-go pensions |
1 |
1 |
1 |
7 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
17 |
Reference-dependent preferences, time inconsistency, and unfunded pensions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
8 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
19 |
Rejuveniles and Growth |
0 |
0 |
0 |
33 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
124 |
Rejuveniles and Growth |
0 |
0 |
0 |
37 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
195 |
Rejuveniles and growth |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
Rejuveniles and growth |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
Reliance, Composition, and Inflation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
Reliance, Composition, and Inflation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
181 |
Resolving Intergenerational Conflict over the Environment under the Pareto Criterion |
0 |
0 |
0 |
28 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
171 |
Resolving intergenerational conflict over the environment under the Pareto criterion |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
11 |
Resurrecting Equilibria Through Cycles |
0 |
0 |
0 |
27 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
86 |
Resurrecting Equilibria Through Cycles in an Overlapping Generations Model of Money |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
51 |
Resurrecting equilibria through cycles in an overlapping generations model of money |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
Seigniorage in a neoclassical economy: some computational results |
0 |
0 |
0 |
167 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
685 |
Social Security and Intergenerational Redistribution |
0 |
0 |
0 |
78 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
210 |
Social security and intergenerational redistribution |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
Social security and intergenerational redistribution |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
Some Even More Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
666 |
Sub-Optimality of the Friedman Rule in Townsend's Turnpike and Stochastic Relocation Models of Money: Do Finite Lives and Initial Dates Matter? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
19 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
256 |
Sub-Optimality of the Friedman Rule in Townsends Turnpike and Limited Communication Models of money: Do finite lives and initial dates matter? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
55 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
609 |
Sub-optimality of the Friedman rule in Townsend's turnpike and stochastic relocation models of money: do finite lives and initial dates matter? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
7 |
Sub-optimality of the Friedman rule in Townsend's turnpike and stochastic relocation models of money: do finite lives and initial dates matter? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
Symmetric reduced form voting |
1 |
1 |
6 |
36 |
1 |
4 |
29 |
102 |
The Fight-or-Flight Response to the Joneses |
0 |
0 |
1 |
83 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
212 |
The Fight-or-Flight Response to the Joneses and Income Inequality |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
15 |
The Intergenerational Welfare State |
0 |
0 |
0 |
67 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
192 |
The Intergenerational Welfare State and The Rise and Fall of Pay‐As‐You‐Go Pensions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
3 |
6 |
The Non-Monotonic Relationship Between Seigniorage and Inequality |
0 |
0 |
0 |
36 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
456 |
The Role of Money in Two Alternative Models: When is the Friedman Rule Optimal, and Why? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
117 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
754 |
The Tobin effect and the Friedman rule |
0 |
0 |
0 |
320 |
1 |
2 |
7 |
1,649 |
The fight-or-flight response to the Joneses and inequality |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
12 |
The non-monotonic relationship between seigniorage and inequality |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
5 |
The non-monotonic relationship between seigniorage and inequality |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
The role of money in two alternative models: When is the Friedman rule optimal, and why? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
7 |
The role of money in two alternative models: When is the Friedman rule optimal, and why? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
Tight Money Policies and Inflation Revisited |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
456 |
Tight Money Policies and Inflation Revisited |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
25 |
Tight money policies and inflation revisited |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
Time inconsistency and endogenous borrowing constraints |
0 |
0 |
0 |
15 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
32 |
Time inconsistency and endogenous borrowing constraints |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
16 |
Two-Period Cycles in a Three-Period Overlapping Generations Model |
0 |
0 |
0 |
12 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
493 |
Understanding the Cost Difference Between Intraday and Overnight Liquidity |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
148 |
Understanding the Roles of Money, or When is the Friedman Rule Optimal, and Why? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
84 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
544 |
Understanding the cost difference between intraday and overnight liquidity |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
12 |
26 |
Unemployment, Credit Rationing, and Capital Accumulation: A Tale of Two Frictions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
239 |
Unfunded Pensions and Endogenous Labor Supply |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
5 |
Unfunded Pensions and Endogenous Labor Supply |
0 |
0 |
0 |
21 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
94 |
Unfunded pensions and endogenous labor supply |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
Unfunded pensions and endogenous labor supply |
0 |
0 |
0 |
53 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
144 |
Unsafe Sex, AIDS, and Development |
2 |
2 |
2 |
112 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
979 |
Voting for immiserizing income redistribution in the Meltzer-Richard model |
0 |
0 |
0 |
16 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
123 |
Voting for income-immiserizing redistribution in the Meltzer-Richard model |
0 |
0 |
1 |
47 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
114 |
Voting for income-immiserizing redistribution in the Meltzer-Richard model |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
Voting for income-immiserizing redistribution in the Meltzer-Richard model |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
5 |
What Do Information Frictions Do? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
45 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
279 |
What do Information Frictions Do? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
12 |
What do Information Frictions Do? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
36 |
What do Information Frictions do? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
What do Information Frictions do? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
111 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
613 |
What do information frictions do? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
65 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
301 |
Who is Afraid of the Friedman Rule |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
Who is Afraid of the Friedman Rule? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
51 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
223 |
Who is Afraid of the Friedman Rule? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
67 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
343 |
Who is afraid of the Friedman rule? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
56 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
282 |
Why Does Overnight Liquidity Cost More Than Intraday Liquidity? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
28 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
128 |
Why Mandate Young Borrowers to Contribute to their Retirement Accounts? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
63 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
103 |
Why does overnight liquidity cost more than intraday liquidity? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
60 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
296 |
Why does overnight liquidity cost more than intraday liquidity? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Why does overnight liquidity cost more than intraday liquidity? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
Why mandate young borrowers to contribute to their retirement accounts? |
0 |
0 |
2 |
7 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
14 |
Why mandate young borrowers to contribute to their retirement accounts? |
1 |
1 |
1 |
51 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
67 |
Total Working Papers |
27 |
34 |
75 |
5,450 |
46 |
85 |
287 |
27,804 |
Journal Article |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
A dynamic-efficiency rationale for public investment in the health of the young |
0 |
0 |
0 |
17 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
88 |
A dynamic‐efficiency rationale for public investment in the health of the young |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
13 |
A rational-choice model of Covid-19 transmission with endogenous quarantining and two-sided prevention |
0 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
20 |
Businesses in high-income zip codes often saw sharper visit reductions during the COVID-19 pandemic |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
3 |
Can financial intermediation induce endogenous fluctuations |
0 |
0 |
0 |
39 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
131 |
Can optimal unfunded public pensions co-exist with voluntary private retirement savings? |
0 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
1 |
2 |
5 |
7 |
Chetan Ghate, Pawan Gopalakrishnan, and Srishti Grover: the Mahalanobis growth model—a macrodynamics approach |
0 |
0 |
3 |
5 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
19 |
Child survival and contraception choice: Theory and evidence |
0 |
0 |
5 |
6 |
0 |
1 |
16 |
21 |
Choosing to keep up with the Joneses and income inequality |
0 |
2 |
3 |
32 |
1 |
3 |
4 |
157 |
Commitment and partial naïveté: Early withdrawal penalties on retirement accounts |
0 |
1 |
4 |
4 |
0 |
2 |
7 |
8 |
Contraception and the Demographic Transition |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
34 |
Credit market imperfections, income distribution, and capital accumulation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
196 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1,205 |
Deviant generations, Ricardian equivalence, and growth cycles |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
60 |
Do workers discriminate against their out-group employers? Evidence from an online platform economy |
1 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
1 |
2 |
5 |
5 |
ENDOGENOUS BORROWING CONSTRAINTS AND WEALTH INEQUALITY |
0 |
0 |
2 |
25 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
96 |
Exponential-growth prediction bias and compliance with safety measures related to COVID-19 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
17 |
Fertility choice under child mortality and social norms |
0 |
0 |
2 |
52 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
171 |
Galor, Oded. Discrete Dynamical Systems. Berlin-Heidelberg: Springer Verlag, 2007, 153 pp., $71.96 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
17 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
82 |
HETEROGENEITY, REDISTRIBUTION, AND THE FRIEDMAN RULE |
0 |
0 |
0 |
148 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
525 |
Intergenerational Debt Dynamics Without Tears |
0 |
1 |
1 |
27 |
3 |
5 |
7 |
210 |
Introduction to the special issue “Current themes in economics” |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
4 |
Investigating long-range correlation properties in EEG during complex cognitive tasks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
7 |
Is income inequality linked to infectious disease prevalence? A hypothesis-generating study using tuberculosis |
0 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
Labor Market Search and Optimal Retirement Policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
74 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
422 |
Lectures on Economic Growth |
0 |
0 |
0 |
14 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
44 |
MONETARY POLICY, FISCAL POLICY, AND THE INFLATION TAX: EQUIVALENCE RESULTS |
0 |
0 |
0 |
18 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
58 |
Monetary Economics in Globalised Financial Markets, by Ansgar Belke and Thorsten Polleit. 2009 Springer-Verlag (Heidelberg); ISBN: 978-3-540-71002-8 |
0 |
1 |
9 |
144 |
0 |
2 |
16 |
383 |
Monetary policy arithmetic: some recent contributions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
206 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
747 |
Monetary, Fiscal, and Reserve Requirement Policy in a Simple Monetary Growth Model |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
2 |
3 |
518 |
On myopia as rationale for social security |
0 |
1 |
3 |
17 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
95 |
On the Use of the Inflation Tax When Nondistortionary Taxes Are Available |
0 |
0 |
0 |
83 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
541 |
Optimal choice of monetary policy instruments in an economy with real and liquidity shocks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
27 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
89 |
Optimal health and environmental policies in a pollution-growth nexus |
0 |
0 |
1 |
37 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
159 |
Optimal monetary policy and economic growth |
0 |
0 |
1 |
120 |
3 |
4 |
29 |
395 |
Optimal monetary rules under persistent shocks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
22 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
88 |
Pareto-improving transition to fully funded pensions under myopia |
0 |
0 |
1 |
5 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
14 |
Pareto-improving transition to fully funded pensions under myopia |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
13 |
Patience Cycles |
0 |
0 |
0 |
18 |
0 |
2 |
2 |
85 |
Pension reform and wealth inequality: Theory and evidence |
1 |
3 |
6 |
6 |
1 |
5 |
11 |
11 |
Price Level Volatility: A Simple Model of Money Taxes and Sunspots |
0 |
0 |
1 |
35 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
144 |
Private versus public old-age security |
0 |
0 |
0 |
14 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
90 |
Reference‐dependent preferences, time inconsistency, and pay‐as‐you‐go pensions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
10 |
Rejuveniles and growth |
0 |
0 |
0 |
23 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
165 |
Reliance, composition, and inflation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
31 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
368 |
Resolving intergenerational conflict over the environment under the Pareto criterion |
1 |
1 |
2 |
16 |
2 |
2 |
8 |
69 |
Resurrecting equilibria through cycles in an overlapping generations model of money |
0 |
0 |
0 |
15 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
75 |
Some Even More Unpleasant Monetarist Arithmetic |
0 |
0 |
1 |
340 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
1,665 |
Sub-optimality of the Friedman rule in Townsend's turnpike and stochastic relocation models of money: Do finite lives and initial dates matter? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
28 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
128 |
The Intergenerational Welfare State and the Rise and Fall of Pay‐as‐you‐go Pensions |
1 |
3 |
6 |
28 |
1 |
6 |
11 |
57 |
The fight-or-flight response to the Joneses and inequality |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
148 |
The non-monotonic relationship between seigniorage and inequality |
0 |
0 |
0 |
65 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
412 |
The non‐monotonic relationship between seigniorage and inequality |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
The role of money in two alternative models: When is the Friedman rule optimal, and why? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
122 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
452 |
Tight money policies and inflation revisited |
0 |
0 |
0 |
154 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1,264 |
Tight money policies and inflation revisited |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
Two-period cycles in a three-period overlapping generations model |
0 |
0 |
0 |
139 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
418 |
UNFUNDED PENSIONS AND ENDOGENOUS LABOR SUPPLY |
0 |
0 |
0 |
33 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
111 |
USEFULNESS OF THE CONSTRAINED PLANNING PROBLEM IN A MODEL OF MONEY |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
34 |
Understanding the cost difference between intraday and overnight liquidity |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
120 |
Unemployment, credit rationing, and capital accumulation: a tale of two frictions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
164 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
913 |
VOTING FOR INCOME-IMMISERIZING REDISTRIBUTION IN THE MELTZER–RICHARD MODEL |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
71 |
Volatility and Growth: The Clarendon Lectures in Economics |
0 |
0 |
0 |
11 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
37 |
WHO IS AFRAID OF THE FRIEDMAN RULE? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
29 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
126 |
What do information frictions do? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
45 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
202 |
Why does overnight liquidity cost more than intraday liquidity? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
27 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
124 |
Why mandate young borrowers to contribute to their retirement accounts? |
0 |
0 |
3 |
15 |
0 |
1 |
7 |
53 |
Total Journal Articles |
5 |
19 |
63 |
2,752 |
20 |
53 |
210 |
13,816 |