Access Statistics for Mark Blaug
Author contact details at EconPapers.
Journal Article |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
A Brief History of History of Economic Thought Teaching in the Netherlands |
0 |
0 |
0 |
18 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
52 |
A Tribute to Dick Netzer and The Subsidized Muse |
0 |
0 |
0 |
37 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
178 |
An Economic Analysis of Personal Earnings in Thailand |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
165 |
Book Reviews |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
14 |
Book reviews |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
16 |
Bowles and Gintis revisited. Correspondence and contradiction in education theory: Edited by Mike Cole. London, New York, Philadelphia: The Falmer Press, 1988. 255 pp. U.S.$25.00 (paper), $53.00 (cloth) |
1 |
1 |
1 |
69 |
2 |
2 |
4 |
738 |
Classical Economics Reconsidered. By Thomas Sowell. (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1974. Pp. 152. $9.00.) |
0 |
1 |
1 |
6 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
17 |
Comment On D. Wade Hands, “Karl Popper and Economic Methodology: A New Look” |
0 |
0 |
0 |
36 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
74 |
Comments on E. Schlicht’s On Custom in the Economy (1998) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
14 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
105 |
Comments on M. Peston and H. Glennerster |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
13 |
Development of British Monetary Orthodoxy, 1797–1875. By Frank Whitson Fetter. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1965. Pp. ix, 296. $6.00 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
41 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
131 |
Disturbing Currents in Modern Economics |
0 |
0 |
3 |
55 |
0 |
0 |
14 |
117 |
Economic dimensions of education: Douglas M. Windham, ed. A Report of a Committee of the National Academy of Education. Washington, D.C.: National Academy of Education, 1979. Pp. viii, 160. No price listed (paper) |
0 |
0 |
2 |
71 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
308 |
FOREWORD |
0 |
0 |
0 |
22 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
60 |
Final comments on the plenary session on Baumol and Bowen |
0 |
0 |
1 |
17 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
50 |
Henry George: rebel with a cause |
0 |
0 |
0 |
73 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
236 |
Introduction to the plenary session on the 30th anniversary of The performing arts: An economic dilemma by Baumol and Bowen — Ninth International Conference on Cultural Economics Boston 8–11 May 1996 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
39 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
112 |
Is Competition Such a Good Thing? Static Efficiency versus Dynamic Efficiency |
0 |
0 |
2 |
338 |
2 |
2 |
6 |
889 |
Kuhn Versus Lakatos, or Paradigms Versus Research Programmes in the History of Economics |
0 |
0 |
2 |
169 |
2 |
4 |
19 |
427 |
Kurz and Salvadori on the Sraffian Interpretation of the Surplus Approach |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
25 |
La signification de la corrélation « éducation-salaire » |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
77 |
Marx on Exploitation and Inequality: An Essay in Marxian Analytical Economics. By Arun Bose. Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1980. Pp. xvi, 237. $14.50. - Marx against Marxism. By Julius I. Loewenstein. Boston: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1980. Pp. xiii, 222. $20.00 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
50 |
0 |
2 |
3 |
203 |
Misunderstanding Classical Economics: The Sraffian Interpretation of the Surplus Approach |
0 |
0 |
2 |
57 |
0 |
2 |
6 |
150 |
Neil de Marchi and Crauford D.W. Goodwin (eds.), Economic Engagements with Art |
0 |
0 |
1 |
27 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
134 |
No History of Ideas, Please, We're Economists |
0 |
1 |
4 |
691 |
13 |
15 |
32 |
1,723 |
No History of Ideas, Please, We're Economists: Response |
0 |
0 |
0 |
155 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
498 |
Not Only an Economist—Autobiographical Reflections of a Historian of Economic Thought |
0 |
0 |
0 |
12 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
18 |
Obituary |
0 |
0 |
0 |
36 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
140 |
On the Historiography of Economics |
0 |
1 |
5 |
67 |
0 |
1 |
9 |
130 |
On the Historiography of Economics: A Correspondence |
0 |
0 |
2 |
88 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
147 |
Rational vs historical reconstruction - a counter-note on Signorino's note on Blaug |
0 |
0 |
1 |
40 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
155 |
Recent Biographies of Keynes |
0 |
2 |
2 |
51 |
0 |
2 |
5 |
186 |
Ricardo on Taxation. By C. S. Shoup. New York: Columbia University Press, 1960. Pp. 285. $6.00 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
41 |
Samuel Hollander, The Economics of Karl Marx: Analysis and Application (New York: Cambridge University Press, 2008), pp. xvi, 532. HB $130. ISBN 978-0-521-79078-9. PB $65, ISBN 978-0-521-79399-5 |
0 |
2 |
4 |
37 |
1 |
3 |
11 |
100 |
Say's Law of Markets: What Did It Mean and Why Should We Care? |
0 |
0 |
8 |
271 |
0 |
1 |
17 |
784 |
Schooling in Capitalist America: Educational Reform and the Contradictions of Economic Life |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
15 |
Second Thoughts on the Keynesian Revolution |
0 |
2 |
4 |
60 |
0 |
4 |
8 |
112 |
Statement |
1 |
1 |
1 |
5 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
28 |
Studies in the Theory of Money 1690–1776. By Douglas Vickers. Philadelphia: Chilton Company, 1959. Pp. ix, 313. $6.50 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
22 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
65 |
THE PRODUCTIVITY OF CAPITAL IN THE LANCASHIRE COTTON INDUSTRY DURING THE NINETEENTH CENTURY |
0 |
0 |
1 |
7 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
33 |
The Classical Economists and the Factory Acts — a Re-examination |
0 |
0 |
0 |
17 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
56 |
The Current State of the British Economics Profession |
0 |
0 |
0 |
57 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
223 |
The Distribution of Schooling and the Distribution of Earnings: Raising the School Leaving Age in 1972 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
195 |
The Empirical Status of Human Capital Theory: A Slightly Jaundiced Survey |
1 |
9 |
41 |
1,316 |
3 |
17 |
84 |
3,037 |
The Formalist Revolution of the 1950s |
0 |
2 |
4 |
104 |
0 |
2 |
15 |
246 |
The Fundamental Theorems of Modern Welfare Economics, Historically Contemplated |
0 |
0 |
1 |
118 |
1 |
2 |
22 |
380 |
The German hegemony of location theory: a puzzle in the history of economic thought |
0 |
0 |
3 |
48 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
103 |
The Myth of the Old Poor Law and the Making of the New |
0 |
1 |
3 |
174 |
0 |
3 |
15 |
462 |
The Poor Law Report Reexamined |
0 |
1 |
2 |
57 |
0 |
2 |
5 |
154 |
The Private and the Social Returns on Investment in Education: Some Results for Great Britain |
1 |
1 |
2 |
9 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
30 |
The Problems with Formalism |
0 |
0 |
2 |
15 |
1 |
2 |
6 |
54 |
The Trade-Off between Rigor and Relevance: Sraffian Economics as a Case in Point |
0 |
1 |
3 |
51 |
1 |
3 |
9 |
153 |
The distributional effects of higher education subsidies |
0 |
0 |
2 |
69 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
164 |
Vaizey (John) et al. - The Political Economy of Education |
0 |
0 |
0 |
15 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
46 |
Was There a Marginal Revolution? |
1 |
5 |
13 |
325 |
2 |
6 |
23 |
845 |
Where Are We Now On Cultural Economics |
1 |
3 |
11 |
30 |
2 |
4 |
17 |
52 |
Where are we now in British health economics? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
44 |
Where are we now in the economics of education? |
0 |
2 |
5 |
387 |
0 |
3 |
11 |
857 |
Total Journal Articles |
6 |
37 |
143 |
5,514 |
40 |
96 |
392 |
15,567 |
1 registered items for which data could not be found
Book |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Adam Smith (1723–1790) |
0 |
0 |
3 |
10 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
70 |
Alfred Marshall (1842–1924) and Francis Edgeworth (1845–1926) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
33 |
Aristotle (384–322 BC) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
14 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
77 |
Arthur Pigou (1877–1959) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
0 |
2 |
13 |
48 |
Bertil Ohlin (1899–1979) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
22 |
Carl Menger (1840–1921) |
0 |
0 |
1 |
13 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
38 |
David Hume (1711–1776) and James Steuart (1712–1780) |
0 |
0 |
2 |
23 |
1 |
2 |
4 |
78 |
David Ricardo (1772–1823) |
0 |
0 |
4 |
23 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
87 |
Dissenters: Charles Fourier (1772–1837), Henri de St Simon (1760–1825), Pierre–Joseph Proudhon (1809–1865), John A. Hobson (1858–1940) |
0 |
0 |
1 |
7 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
42 |
Economic Theories, True or False? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
28 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
79 |
Economic Theory in Retrospect |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
11 |
50 |
1,273 |
Economics of Education |
1 |
1 |
2 |
25 |
2 |
3 |
10 |
76 |
Edward Chamberlin (1899–1967) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
29 |
Eugen von Böhm–Bawerk (1851–1914) and Friedrich von Wieser (1851–1926) |
0 |
0 |
1 |
10 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
56 |
Francois Quesnay (1694–1774) |
1 |
2 |
3 |
25 |
12 |
30 |
60 |
202 |
Frank Knight (1885–1972), Henry Simons (1899–1946) and Joseph Schumpeter (1883–1950) |
0 |
1 |
2 |
4 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
23 |
George Scrope (1797–1876), Thomas Attwood (1783–1856), Edwin Chadwick (1800–1890) and John Cairnes (1823–1875) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
24 |
Great Economists before Keynes |
0 |
1 |
5 |
182 |
0 |
1 |
11 |
487 |
Great economists since keynes |
0 |
1 |
4 |
87 |
1 |
2 |
8 |
227 |
Gustav Schmoller (1838–1917) and Werner Sombart (1863–1941) |
0 |
1 |
2 |
17 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
60 |
Harold Hotelling (1895–1973), Lionel Robbins (1898–1984), Clark Warburton (1896–1979), John Bates Clark (1847–1938) and Ludwig von Mises (1881–1973) |
0 |
0 |
1 |
7 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
18 |
Harry Johnson (1923–1977) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
29 |
Henry George (1839–1897) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
8 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
27 |
Henry Thornton (1760–1815), Jeremy Bentham (1748–1832), James Lauderdale (1759–1839) and Simonde de Sismondi (1773–1842) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
37 |
Irving Fisher (1867–1947), Arthur Hadley (1856–1930), Ragnar Frisch (1895–1973), Friedrich Hayek (1899–1992), Allyn Young (1876–1929) and Ugo Mazzola (1863–1899) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
25 |
James Mill (1773–1836), John Rae (1796–1872), Edward West (1782–1828),Thomas Joplin (1790–1847) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
23 |
James Wilson (1805–1860), Issac Butt (1813–1879), T.E. Cliffe Leslie (1827–1882) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
15 |
Jean-Baptiste Say (1767–1832) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
27 |
Joan Robinson (1903–1983) and George Shackle (1903–1992) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
18 |
Johann von Thünen (1783–1850), Augustin Cournot (1801–1877) and Jules Dupuit (1804–1866) |
0 |
1 |
3 |
11 |
1 |
3 |
8 |
50 |
John Maynard Keynes (1883–1946) |
0 |
0 |
3 |
19 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
59 |
Karl Marx (1818–1883) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
52 |
Knut Wicksell (1851–1926) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
26 |
Léon Walras (1834–1910) |
0 |
0 |
1 |
7 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
21 |
Michal Kalecki (1899–1970) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
36 |
Not Only an Economist |
0 |
0 |
3 |
31 |
2 |
3 |
13 |
104 |
Piero Sraffa (1898–1983) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
13 |
Pre-Classical Economists Volume I: Charles Davenant (1656–1714) and William Petty (1623–1687) |
0 |
0 |
2 |
31 |
0 |
0 |
12 |
151 |
Pre-Classical Economists Volume II |
0 |
0 |
0 |
15 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
74 |
Pre-Classical Economists Volume III: John Law (1671–1729) and Bernard Mandeville (1660–1733) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
16 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
62 |
Ramsay McCulloch (1789–1864), Nassau Senior (1790–1864) and Robert Torrens (1780–1864) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
43 |
Richard Cantillon (1680–1734) and Jacques Turgot (1727–1781) |
0 |
0 |
1 |
38 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
208 |
St Thomas Aquinas (1225–1274) |
1 |
7 |
22 |
110 |
25 |
85 |
238 |
765 |
The Early Mercantilists: Thomas Mun (1571–1641), Edward Misselden (1608–1634) and Gerard de Malynes (1586–1623) |
0 |
6 |
22 |
240 |
3 |
13 |
56 |
698 |
The Economics of Education and the Education of an Economist |
0 |
1 |
5 |
85 |
3 |
5 |
21 |
268 |
The Historiography of Economics |
1 |
3 |
13 |
73 |
1 |
5 |
28 |
196 |
The Later Mercantilists: Josiah Child (1603–1699) and John Locke (1632–1704) |
0 |
1 |
5 |
71 |
1 |
4 |
13 |
247 |
The Methodology of Economics |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
17 |
1,897 |
The Quantity Theory of Money |
3 |
12 |
41 |
511 |
8 |
45 |
119 |
1,481 |
Thomas Robert Malthus (1766–1834) and John Stuart Mill (1806–1873) |
1 |
1 |
1 |
14 |
4 |
7 |
17 |
92 |
Thomas Tooke (1774–1858), Mountifort Longfield (1802–1884) and Richard Jones (1790–1855) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
23 |
Thorstein Veblen (1857–1929) |
0 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
28 |
Vilfredo Pareto (1848–1923) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
27 |
Wesley Mitchell (1874–1948), John Commons (1862–1945), Clarence Ayres (1891–1972) |
0 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
26 |
William Whewell (1794–1866), Dionysius Lardner (1793–1859) and Charles Babbage (1792–1871) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
1 |
2 |
5 |
35 |
Total Books |
8 |
39 |
155 |
1,858 |
75 |
238 |
768 |
9,932 |
|
|