Working Paper |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
"Near" Weighted Utilitarian Characterizations of Pareto Optima |
0 |
0 |
4 |
17 |
0 |
1 |
8 |
36 |
"Revolving Doors" and Optimal Tolerance for Agency Collusion |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
175 |
A Dynamic Theory of Holdup |
0 |
0 |
0 |
117 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
460 |
A dynamic theory of holdup |
0 |
0 |
0 |
90 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
388 |
Adverse Selection in Class Action Suits |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
144 |
An Analysis of Top Trading Cycles in Two-Sided Matching Markets |
0 |
0 |
0 |
12 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
50 |
An Analysis of Top Trading Cycles in Two-Sided Matching Markets |
0 |
0 |
0 |
29 |
0 |
2 |
5 |
34 |
Asymmetric Information about Rivals’ Types in Standard Auctions: An Experiment |
0 |
0 |
0 |
89 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
243 |
Asymmetric Information about Rivals’ Types in Standard Auctions: An Experiment |
0 |
0 |
0 |
45 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
208 |
Asymmetric information about rivals' types in standard auctions: an experiment |
0 |
0 |
0 |
70 |
0 |
2 |
6 |
285 |
Asymptotic Equivalence of Probabilistic Serial and Random Priority Mechanisms |
0 |
0 |
0 |
98 |
2 |
2 |
4 |
573 |
Auctions with budget-constrained buyers: a nonequivalence result |
0 |
0 |
0 |
43 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
346 |
Bailout Stigma |
0 |
0 |
0 |
49 |
0 |
1 |
14 |
176 |
Bailout Stigma |
1 |
1 |
3 |
5 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
25 |
Bailout Stigma |
0 |
1 |
3 |
10 |
0 |
2 |
8 |
44 |
Buyer Alliances and Managed Competition |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
675 |
Caps on Political Lobbying |
1 |
3 |
7 |
527 |
3 |
8 |
18 |
3,757 |
Caps on Political Lobbying: Reply |
0 |
0 |
0 |
16 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
89 |
Collusion-proof implementation of optimal mechanisms |
0 |
0 |
0 |
60 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
152 |
Contract Damages and Cooperative Investments |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
331 |
Contractual Remedies to the Holdup Problem: A Dynamic Perspective |
0 |
0 |
0 |
151 |
1 |
3 |
5 |
677 |
Contractual remedies to the holdup problem: a dynamic perspective |
0 |
0 |
0 |
33 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
204 |
Cooperative Investments and the Value of Contracting |
0 |
0 |
2 |
254 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
837 |
Cooperative Investments and the Value of Contracting: Coase vs Williamson |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
875 |
Customer Return Policies for Experience Goods |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
12 |
277 |
Decoupling Liability: Optimal Incentives for Care and Litigation |
0 |
0 |
1 |
56 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
243 |
Design Competition through Multidimensional Auctions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
528 |
Difference-form contests and the robustness of all-pay auctions |
0 |
0 |
2 |
116 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
411 |
Efficiency and Stability in Large Matching Markets |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
25 |
Efficiency and Stability in Large Matching Markets |
0 |
0 |
0 |
25 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
85 |
Efficiency and Stability in Large Matching Markets |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
8 |
Efficiency and Stability in Large Matching Markets |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
40 |
Efficiency, Justified Envy, and Incentives in Priority-Based Matching |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
28 |
Efficiency, Justified Envy, and Incentives in Priority-Based Matching |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
22 |
Evaluating the Impact of Privacy Regulation on E-Commerce Firms: Evidence from Apple’s App Tracking Transparency |
0 |
0 |
5 |
5 |
3 |
4 |
15 |
15 |
Expanding "Choice" in School Choice |
0 |
0 |
2 |
19 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
141 |
Expanding 'Choice' in School Choice |
0 |
1 |
2 |
23 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
187 |
Expanding “Choice” in School Choice |
0 |
0 |
0 |
32 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
126 |
Exploiting Plaintiffs Through Settlement: Divide and Conquer |
0 |
0 |
0 |
34 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
118 |
Generalized reduced-form auctions: a network-flow approach |
0 |
0 |
0 |
61 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
182 |
How to Divide the Possession of a Football? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
154 |
Incomplete Contracts and Cooperative Investments |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
617 |
Keeping the Listener Engaged: a Dynamic Model of Bayesian Persuasion |
0 |
1 |
1 |
28 |
0 |
2 |
3 |
31 |
Know thy enemies: knowledge of rivals' types and its effect on auctions |
0 |
2 |
3 |
38 |
0 |
2 |
4 |
196 |
Lawyer Advising in Evidence Disclosure |
0 |
0 |
0 |
22 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
178 |
Legal Advice and Evidence with Bayesian and non-Bayesian Adjudicators |
0 |
0 |
0 |
28 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
45 |
Leveraging Uncertainties to Infer Preferences: Robust Analysis of School Choice |
0 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
7 |
Market versus Non-Market Assignment of Initial Ownership |
0 |
0 |
0 |
26 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
187 |
Minimizing Justified Envy in School Choice: The Design of New Orleans' OneApp |
0 |
0 |
1 |
41 |
0 |
1 |
9 |
144 |
Notes on the Microfoundations of Monetary Economics |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
601 |
Opinion as Incentives |
0 |
0 |
0 |
56 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
181 |
Optimal Collusion-Proof Auctions |
0 |
0 |
1 |
70 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
191 |
Optimal Design for Social Learning |
0 |
0 |
0 |
36 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
69 |
Optimal Design for Social Learning |
0 |
0 |
0 |
22 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
78 |
Optimal Design of Research Contests |
0 |
0 |
0 |
221 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
703 |
Optimal Dynamic Allocation of Attention |
0 |
1 |
1 |
54 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
75 |
Optimal Queue Design |
0 |
0 |
1 |
5 |
0 |
1 |
8 |
13 |
Optimal Use of Information Litigation: Should Regulatory Information be Withheld to Deter Frivolus Suits? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
113 |
Optimal incentives for teams |
0 |
0 |
0 |
394 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
1,082 |
Pandering to Persuade |
0 |
0 |
0 |
18 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
106 |
Pandering to Persuade |
0 |
0 |
0 |
12 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
67 |
Pandering to Persuade |
0 |
0 |
0 |
26 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
187 |
Payoff Equivalence of Efficient Mechanisms in Large Matching Markets |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
Payoff Equivalence of Efficient Mechanisms in Large Matching Markets |
0 |
0 |
0 |
13 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
40 |
Payoff Equivalence of Efficient Mechanisms in Large Matching Markets |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
19 |
Payoff Equivalence of Efficient Mechanisms in Large Matching Markets |
0 |
0 |
0 |
15 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
33 |
Predictive Enforcement |
0 |
0 |
5 |
5 |
1 |
5 |
19 |
19 |
Prizes versus Contracts as Incentives for Innovation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
93 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
133 |
Prizes versus Contracts as Incentives for Innovation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
18 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
19 |
Prizes versus Contracts as Incentives for Innovation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
94 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
150 |
Prizes versus Contracts as Incentives for Innovation |
0 |
0 |
2 |
98 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
104 |
Prolonged Learning and Hasty Stopping: The Wald Problem With Ambiguity |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
28 |
Prolonged Learning and Hasty Stopping: the Wald Problem with Ambiguity |
0 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
1 |
3 |
3 |
7 |
Prolonged Learning and Hasty Stopping: the Wald Problem with Ambiguity |
1 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
12 |
Prolonged Learning and Hasty Stopping: the Wald Problem with Ambiguity |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
Revenue Comparisons for Auctions When Bidders Have Arbitrary Types |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
71 |
Revenue Comparisons for Auctions when Bidders Have Arbitrary Types |
0 |
0 |
0 |
17 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
106 |
Robustly Optimal Mechanisms for Selling Multiple Goods |
0 |
0 |
0 |
25 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
63 |
Section 365, Mandatory Bankruptcy Rules and Inefficient Continuance |
0 |
0 |
1 |
55 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
676 |
Section 365: mandatory bankruptcy rules and inefficient continuation |
0 |
0 |
1 |
51 |
1 |
2 |
4 |
423 |
Stable Matching with Mistaken Agents |
0 |
0 |
1 |
30 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
54 |
Statistical Discrimination in Ratings-Guided Markets |
1 |
1 |
1 |
9 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
32 |
Strategic Judgment Proofing |
0 |
0 |
0 |
17 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
185 |
Strategic Judgment Proofing |
0 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
105 |
The Economics of Collective Negociation: Consolidation of Claims by Multiple Plaintiffs |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
192 |
The Effect of Privacy Regulation on the Data Industry: Empirical Evidence from GDPR |
0 |
1 |
3 |
107 |
0 |
2 |
12 |
325 |
The Hold-up Problem |
0 |
0 |
4 |
1,110 |
1 |
1 |
18 |
4,020 |
The Optimal Mechanism For Selling To Budget-Constrained Consumers |
0 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
1 |
3 |
3 |
19 |
The Optimal Mechanism for Selling to Budget-Constrained Consumers |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
109 |
The Optimal Mechanism for Selling to Budget-Constrained Consumers |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
153 |
The Optimal Mechanism for Selling to Budget-Constrained Consumers |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
715 |
The Role of Precedents in Repeated Litigation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
226 |
Weak Monotone Comparative Statics |
0 |
0 |
1 |
38 |
2 |
4 |
8 |
44 |
Total Working Papers |
4 |
16 |
63 |
5,042 |
35 |
86 |
329 |
26,331 |
Journal Article |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
A Dynamic Theory of Holdup |
0 |
0 |
1 |
182 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
740 |
An experimental study of sponsored-search auctions |
0 |
0 |
1 |
13 |
2 |
2 |
5 |
49 |
Assigning Resources to Budget-Constrained Agents |
1 |
1 |
2 |
42 |
1 |
2 |
5 |
171 |
Asymmetric information about rivals' types in standard auctions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
34 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
126 |
Asymmetric information about rivals' types in standard auctions: An experiment |
0 |
0 |
0 |
68 |
2 |
3 |
3 |
295 |
Asymptotic Equivalence of Probabilistic Serial and Random Priority Mechanisms |
0 |
0 |
1 |
41 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
238 |
Bidding with Securities: Comment |
0 |
0 |
0 |
33 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
166 |
Brave New World of Market Design |
0 |
0 |
1 |
23 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
100 |
Buy-in through goldplating: The effect of defense profit policy on quality determination |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
105 |
Buyer Alliances and Managed Competition |
0 |
0 |
0 |
18 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
186 |
Can a Contract Solve Hold-Up When Investments Have Externalities? A Comment on De Fraja (1999) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
24 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
91 |
Caps on Political Lobbying |
1 |
3 |
10 |
172 |
2 |
4 |
18 |
557 |
Caps on Political Lobbying: Reply |
0 |
0 |
0 |
16 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
142 |
Competitive Procurement with Corruption |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
1 |
2 |
5 |
1,018 |
Contract Damages and Cooperative Investments |
0 |
0 |
0 |
80 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
596 |
Cooperative Investments and the Value of Contracting |
0 |
0 |
0 |
391 |
0 |
1 |
5 |
1,357 |
Credit Market Speculation and the Cost of Capital |
0 |
0 |
1 |
29 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
126 |
Customer Return Policies for Experience Goods |
1 |
2 |
2 |
114 |
2 |
3 |
12 |
583 |
Decentralized College Admissions |
0 |
2 |
8 |
102 |
0 |
5 |
25 |
457 |
Decoupling Liability: Optimal Incentives for Care and Litigation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
115 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
513 |
Design Competition through Multidimensional Auctions |
0 |
0 |
8 |
655 |
1 |
1 |
21 |
1,419 |
Designing Random Allocation Mechanisms: Theory and Applications |
0 |
1 |
2 |
54 |
3 |
5 |
16 |
311 |
Difference-Form Contests and the Robustness of All-Pay Auctions |
0 |
0 |
2 |
93 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
204 |
Disclosure and Legal Advice |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
48 |
Do breakup fees lead to efficient takeover? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
27 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
115 |
Efficiency and Stability in Large Matching Markets |
0 |
2 |
9 |
18 |
0 |
2 |
20 |
109 |
Efficiency, Justified Envy, and Incentives in Priority-Based Matching |
0 |
0 |
2 |
15 |
1 |
1 |
10 |
57 |
Efficient assignment mechanisms for liquidity-constrained agents |
0 |
0 |
0 |
23 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
73 |
Efficient assignment with interdependent values |
0 |
0 |
0 |
11 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
67 |
Eliciting Multi-Dimensional Care through Liability and Regulation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
8 |
2 |
2 |
4 |
48 |
Equilibrium formation of class action suits |
0 |
0 |
0 |
95 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
436 |
Expanding "Choice" in School Choice |
0 |
0 |
1 |
28 |
0 |
3 |
16 |
200 |
Expected revenue of all-pay auctions and first-price sealed-bid auctions with budget constraints |
0 |
0 |
0 |
153 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
386 |
Exploiting Plaintiffs through Settlement: Divide and Conquer |
0 |
0 |
0 |
41 |
0 |
2 |
5 |
194 |
Generalized Reduced‐Form Auctions: A Network‐Flow Approach |
0 |
0 |
0 |
27 |
0 |
2 |
3 |
147 |
How to divide the possession of a football? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
17 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
93 |
Joint Liability and Peer Monitoring under Group Lending |
0 |
0 |
1 |
229 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
771 |
Keeping the Listener Engaged: A Dynamic Model of Bayesian Persuasion |
0 |
1 |
5 |
12 |
0 |
5 |
26 |
46 |
Mechanism design with a liquidity constrained buyer: The 2 x 2 case1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
25 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
114 |
Opinions as Incentives |
0 |
0 |
0 |
167 |
0 |
1 |
7 |
599 |
Optimal Design of Research Contests |
0 |
0 |
3 |
144 |
0 |
1 |
7 |
539 |
Optimal Dynamic Allocation of Attention |
0 |
1 |
4 |
51 |
0 |
3 |
8 |
305 |
Optimal Incentives for Teams |
0 |
3 |
4 |
528 |
1 |
4 |
11 |
1,357 |
Optimal Use of Information in Litigation: Should Regulatory Information Be Withheld to Deter Frivolous Suits? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
14 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
172 |
Optimal collusion-proof auctions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
98 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
297 |
Pandering to Persuade |
0 |
0 |
3 |
53 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
271 |
Payoff equivalence of efficient mechanisms in large matching markets |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
43 |
Performance-Based Pricing for Nucleaer Power Plants |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
2 |
3 |
3 |
75 |
Performance-Based Pricing for Nuclear Power Plants |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
Prizes versus Contracts as Incentives for Innovation |
0 |
0 |
4 |
9 |
1 |
1 |
9 |
34 |
Products Liability, Signaling and Disclosure. Comment |
0 |
0 |
0 |
15 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
69 |
Prolonged Learning and Hasty Stopping: The Wald Problem with Ambiguity |
0 |
2 |
6 |
8 |
1 |
5 |
27 |
35 |
Recommender Systems as Mechanisms for Social Learning |
1 |
3 |
35 |
180 |
6 |
11 |
85 |
524 |
Rent Dissipation When Rent Seekers Are Budget Constrained |
0 |
0 |
0 |
61 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
185 |
Resolving Conflicting Preferences in School Choice: The "Boston Mechanism" Reconsidered |
0 |
1 |
2 |
82 |
2 |
7 |
11 |
305 |
Revenue comparisons for auctions when bidders have arbitrary types |
0 |
0 |
0 |
49 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
222 |
Revolving Doors and the Optimal Tolerance for Agency Collusion |
0 |
0 |
2 |
141 |
0 |
2 |
12 |
586 |
Robustly Collusion-Proof Implementation |
0 |
0 |
1 |
95 |
2 |
3 |
6 |
385 |
Section 365, Mandatory Bankruptcy Rules and Inefficient Continuance |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
808 |
Stable Matching in Large Economies |
0 |
0 |
0 |
11 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
81 |
Stable Matching with Mistaken Agents |
0 |
0 |
2 |
7 |
0 |
4 |
16 |
29 |
Standard Auctions with Financially Constrained Bidders |
0 |
0 |
0 |
413 |
0 |
1 |
10 |
1,046 |
Strategic judgment proofing |
0 |
0 |
1 |
15 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
221 |
The Economics of Collective Negotiation in Pretrial Bargaining |
0 |
0 |
0 |
49 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
274 |
The NFL Should Auction Possession in Overtime Games |
0 |
0 |
0 |
30 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
128 |
The Optimal Mechanism for Selling to a Budget-Constrained Buyer |
1 |
1 |
2 |
78 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
227 |
The Role of Precedents in Repeated Litigation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
317 |
The role of lockups in takeover contests |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
21 |
To Trade, or not to Trade, that is the Question: New Roles for Incomplete Contracts in Dynamic Settings |
1 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
5 |
Weak cartels and collusion-proof auctions |
1 |
1 |
4 |
10 |
2 |
2 |
5 |
53 |
Total Journal Articles |
7 |
25 |
131 |
5,370 |
47 |
114 |
499 |
21,667 |