Journal Article |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
A New Dynamic Trade Model of Increasing Returns and Monopolistic Competition |
0 |
0 |
0 |
70 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
457 |
A Note on the Distribution of Trade Gains in a Model of Monopolistic Competition |
0 |
0 |
0 |
48 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
216 |
A decomposition of Ricardian trade gains |
0 |
0 |
0 |
51 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
100 |
A decomposition of the home-market effect |
0 |
0 |
0 |
52 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
174 |
A note on Chamberlinian-Ricardian trade patterns |
0 |
0 |
2 |
12 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
41 |
A simple model of foreign brand penetration under monopolistic competition |
0 |
0 |
0 |
31 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
102 |
A simple model of service offshoring with time zone differences |
0 |
0 |
0 |
24 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
169 |
A simple model of service trade with time zone differences |
0 |
0 |
0 |
70 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
206 |
Agricultural Productivity, Business Services, and Comparative Advantage |
0 |
0 |
1 |
69 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
278 |
Communications networks and virtual economic integration: The case of three countries |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
12 |
Competing Communications Networks and International Trade |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
64 |
Competing Industrial Standards and the Impact of Trade Liberalization |
0 |
0 |
0 |
22 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
91 |
Congestible communications networks and international trade |
0 |
0 |
0 |
71 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
505 |
Congestible communications networks and international trade |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
Congestible communications networks and international trade |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
45 |
Distribution Costs, International Trade and Industrial Location |
0 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
55 |
Expansion of Network Integrations: Two Scenarios, Trade Patterns, and Welfare |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
49 |
Footloose Capital and Comparative Advantage |
0 |
0 |
0 |
19 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
46 |
Footloose Capital and the Locational Advantage of a Hub |
0 |
0 |
1 |
13 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
69 |
Gottinger, H.-W.: Economies of Network Industries |
0 |
0 |
0 |
35 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
198 |
Growth with time zone differences |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
48 |
Growth with time zone differences |
0 |
0 |
2 |
53 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
180 |
HOME MARKET EFFECT AND TRADE COSTS* |
0 |
0 |
0 |
54 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
135 |
INCREASING COSTS IN PRODUCT DIVERSIFICATION AND GAINS FROM TRADE |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
20 |
Indirect Network Effects and Trade Patterns |
0 |
0 |
0 |
8 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
32 |
Indirect network effects and the impact of trade liberalization: A note |
0 |
0 |
0 |
27 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
101 |
Interconnected communications networks and home market effects |
0 |
0 |
0 |
29 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
262 |
Interconnected communications networks and home market effects |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
Interconnectivity of communications networks and international trade |
0 |
0 |
0 |
90 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
567 |
Interconnectivity of communications networks and international trade |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
13 |
Interregional trade, industrial location and import infrastructure |
0 |
0 |
0 |
37 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
122 |
MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION WITH EFFICIENCY GAPS AND A HECKSCHER‐OHLIN TRADE PATTERN* |
0 |
0 |
0 |
43 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
181 |
Monopolistic competition with cross-country technological differences and international trade |
0 |
0 |
0 |
65 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
281 |
NETWORK EXTERNALITIES AND COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE |
0 |
0 |
0 |
37 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
180 |
Network Effects and the Impact of Trade Liberalization |
1 |
1 |
2 |
18 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
68 |
Network Effects and the Impact of Trade Liberalization (Corrected Version) |
0 |
0 |
0 |
6 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
28 |
On Chamberlinian-Ricardian trade patterns with many industries |
0 |
0 |
0 |
15 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
52 |
On Chamberlinian‐Ricardian Trade Patterns |
0 |
0 |
1 |
62 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
271 |
On dynamic Chamberlin-Heckscher-Ohlin trade patterns |
0 |
0 |
0 |
16 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
58 |
On the Emergence of Intra-industry Trade |
0 |
0 |
2 |
65 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
282 |
On the enlargement of interconnected communications networks in the world economy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
22 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
131 |
SHIFT WORKING AND TRADE IN LABOUR SERVICES WITH TIME ZONE DIFFERENCES |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
46 |
SWITCHING COSTS AND THE FOREIGN FIRM'S ENTRY* |
0 |
0 |
0 |
32 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
85 |
Software Provision and the Impact of Market Integration |
0 |
0 |
0 |
14 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
45 |
Strategic Export Policy in a Differentiated Duopoly: A Note |
0 |
0 |
0 |
34 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
158 |
Switching costs and the impact of trade liberalization |
0 |
0 |
0 |
8 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
37 |
Time Preference and Trade Imbalance |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
44 |
Time Zones as a Source of Comparative Advantage |
0 |
0 |
1 |
42 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
122 |
Time Zones, Outsourcing and Patterns of International Trade |
0 |
0 |
0 |
29 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
157 |
Trade Liberalization and Labor Unions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
65 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
310 |
Trade with Time Zone Differences: Factor Market Implications |
0 |
0 |
0 |
31 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
130 |
Virtual integration and endogenous growth in the world economy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
Total Journal Articles |
1 |
1 |
12 |
1,517 |
12 |
25 |
62 |
7,042 |