Journal Article |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
A GOOD ADVISOR |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
31 |
A Note on Connectivity and Stability in Dynamic Network Formation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
15 |
A Proposal for a New Rule of Adverse Possession |
0 |
0 |
1 |
26 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
78 |
A Signaling Theory of the Online Consumer Review Policy |
0 |
0 |
5 |
6 |
0 |
0 |
14 |
16 |
A note on burdens of proof in civil litigation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
8 |
2 |
2 |
2 |
23 |
A note on the non-maximality of the optimal fines when the apprehension probability depends on the offense rate |
0 |
0 |
0 |
11 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
29 |
A performance‐based payment: Signaling the quality of a credence good |
0 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
19 |
A signaling theory of reservation cancellation policies |
0 |
0 |
6 |
7 |
0 |
4 |
17 |
21 |
A signalling explanation for preferential attachment in the evolution of social networks |
0 |
0 |
1 |
27 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
122 |
A theory of consumer referral |
0 |
0 |
0 |
70 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
214 |
An Economic Theory of Deviance |
0 |
0 |
1 |
59 |
0 |
3 |
6 |
849 |
An attorney fee as a signal in pretrial negotiation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
56 |
An economic analysis of the receiver pays principle |
0 |
0 |
0 |
65 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
227 |
Apportionment of liability by the stochastic Shapley value |
0 |
0 |
3 |
9 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
31 |
Assigning Property Rights to Scarce Resources when Individual Wealth Levels are Observable |
0 |
1 |
3 |
5 |
0 |
1 |
5 |
14 |
Attracting the Rival’s Customers in a Model with Switching Costs |
0 |
0 |
0 |
19 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
54 |
Burdens of Proof and Judicial Errors in Civil Litigation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
17 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
44 |
Cheap Talk and Reputation in Repeated Pretrial Negotiation |
0 |
0 |
1 |
63 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
226 |
Cheap Talk by Two Senders in the Presence of Network Externalities |
0 |
1 |
2 |
17 |
0 |
1 |
9 |
76 |
Cheap Talk with Transparent and Monotone Motives from a Seller to an Informed Buyer |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
Comments on the Signaling Theory of IPO Underpricing and Investor Protection Laws |
2 |
3 |
5 |
5 |
3 |
4 |
13 |
13 |
Compensating for unforeseeable damages in torts |
0 |
0 |
0 |
24 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
107 |
Competition for Quality of Services under Net Neutrality and Prioritization |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
Competition in the LM market |
0 |
0 |
0 |
13 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
174 |
Connectivity and Allocation Rule in a Directed Network |
0 |
0 |
0 |
28 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
139 |
Connectivity, stability and efficiency in a network as an information flow |
0 |
0 |
0 |
43 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
123 |
Costly Information Disclosure in Oligopoly |
0 |
0 |
1 |
77 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
252 |
Credible plea bargaining |
0 |
0 |
1 |
37 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
144 |
Credible spatial preemption in a mixed oligopoly |
0 |
0 |
2 |
4 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
10 |
Designing the Efficient Information-Processing Organization |
0 |
0 |
0 |
28 |
1 |
2 |
2 |
122 |
Dutch treat versus Oriental treat |
0 |
0 |
0 |
13 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
120 |
Economics of the Broken Window Theory |
0 |
0 |
1 |
18 |
2 |
4 |
13 |
127 |
Endogenous Internet Structure and Bargaining Power in Interconnection Agreements |
0 |
0 |
0 |
25 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
98 |
Entry Deterrence and Entry Inducement in an Industry with Complementary Products |
0 |
0 |
0 |
19 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
104 |
Entry Invoking |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
60 |
Entry deterrence by cheap talk |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
8 |
Equilibrium National Border and Its Stability |
0 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
29 |
Evolution of revealing emotions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
Evolutionary stability of preferences: altruism, selfishness, and envy |
0 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
0 |
1 |
5 |
14 |
Filing a Nuisance Claim to Induce Successive Lawsuits |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
302 |
Good-faith error and intentional trespassing in adverse possession |
0 |
0 |
1 |
92 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
523 |
HARSH NORMS AND SCREENING FOR LOYALTY |
0 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
31 |
Hyperbolic discounting and the repeated self-control problem |
0 |
0 |
0 |
99 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
249 |
Hypergraph Formation Game |
0 |
1 |
1 |
23 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
114 |
Information Acquisition Activity and Damage Measures |
0 |
0 |
0 |
28 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
93 |
Law and Economics of Artificial Intelligence: Optimal Liability Rules for Accident Losses Caused by Fully Autonomous Vehicles |
1 |
1 |
3 |
3 |
3 |
4 |
9 |
9 |
Limited Liability, Liability Cap, and Pretrial Negotiation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
56 |
Litigation and Pretrial Negotiation under Incomplete Information |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
190 |
Local Interaction, Altruism and the Evolution of Networks |
0 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
33 |
Local loop unbundling and antitrust policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
37 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
144 |
MULTIDIMENSIONAL SIGNALING IN THE LABOR MARKET |
0 |
0 |
0 |
62 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
170 |
Market segmentation and non-uniform Shariah standards in Islamic finance |
0 |
0 |
1 |
13 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
47 |
Monetary policy, fiscal policy and cross signal jamming |
0 |
1 |
1 |
11 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
32 |
Network marketing on a small-world network |
0 |
0 |
0 |
29 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
122 |
ON PREJUDICE |
0 |
0 |
0 |
14 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
105 |
On Public Host Liability |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
31 |
On Variations of Perfect Equilibria |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
18 |
On the Invariance Result of Liability Rules in Oligopoly |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
On the Invariance Result of Net Neutrality |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
9 |
Optimal Law Enforcement when the Offender can Dispose of his Wealth |
0 |
0 |
0 |
13 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
71 |
Optimal online-payment security system and the role of liability sharing |
0 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
16 |
PROFITABILITY OF A MERGER ON NETWORKS |
0 |
0 |
0 |
9 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
34 |
Patent Races for COVID-19 Vaccines and Liability Rules |
0 |
0 |
2 |
17 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
57 |
Peak-load pricing in duopoly |
0 |
0 |
1 |
21 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
103 |
Plea bargaining with multiple defendants and its deterrence effect |
0 |
0 |
1 |
18 |
2 |
3 |
6 |
78 |
Precaution, Cleanup and Liability: A Model of Environmentally Harmful Discharges |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
41 |
Pretrial negotiation behind open doors versus closed doors:: Economic analysis of Rule 408 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
19 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
132 |
Price Discrimination in Public Healthcare |
0 |
0 |
1 |
8 |
3 |
4 |
14 |
65 |
Price asymmetry revisited from a marketing perspective |
0 |
0 |
0 |
14 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
214 |
Pricing an Experience Composite Good as Coordinated Signals |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
41 |
Prioritization between asymmetric content providers |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
Product Compatibility and Technological Innovation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
69 |
0 |
2 |
3 |
185 |
Product compatibility as a signal of quality in a market with network externalities |
0 |
0 |
2 |
55 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
181 |
Proposing New Equilibrium Concepts in Dynamic Games with Noisy Signals |
0 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
1 |
1 |
5 |
9 |
Public monopoly versus mixed oligopoly: product differentiation and social efficiency |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
Quantity Restrictions with Imperfect Enforcement in an Overused Commons: Permissive Regulation to Reduce Overuse? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
8 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
45 |
Rationing as a Signal |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
69 |
Reexamining the Schmalensee effect |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
51 |
Reexamining the effect of packet pricing in the wireless internet |
0 |
0 |
0 |
25 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
122 |
Reexamining the effect of the most-favored-nation provision in input prices on R and D incentives |
0 |
0 |
0 |
27 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
256 |
Revisiting the convergence theorem for competitive bidding in common value auctions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
6 |
STANDARDIZATION IN THE WIRELESS INTERNET MARKET: LESSONS FROM JAPAN AND KOREA |
0 |
0 |
0 |
17 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
60 |
Sanctions in Pre-Trial Discovery |
0 |
0 |
0 |
12 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
88 |
Secrecy and fairness in plea bargaining with multiple defendants |
0 |
0 |
0 |
26 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
133 |
Sell green and buy green: A signaling theory of green products |
1 |
3 |
9 |
13 |
1 |
5 |
21 |
47 |
Seller liability versus platform liability: optimal liability rule and law enforcement in the platform economy |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
0 |
3 |
7 |
7 |
Should refusal to sell be illegal? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
2 |
3 |
31 |
Signal Jamming in Games with Multiple Senders |
0 |
0 |
1 |
129 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
507 |
Signal Jamming in Pretrial Negotiation with Multiple Defendants |
0 |
0 |
1 |
77 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
290 |
Single-Undertaking and Sectoral Approach |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
37 |
Standardization in electronic money |
0 |
0 |
0 |
72 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
207 |
Stigma in divorces and its deterrence effect |
0 |
0 |
0 |
35 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
166 |
Strategic delegation and second mover advantage in duopoly |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
Strict liability versus negligence in the case of data breach |
0 |
0 |
2 |
2 |
1 |
2 |
8 |
8 |
Strict liability versus negligence when the injurer's activity involves positive externalities |
1 |
1 |
1 |
53 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
265 |
THE REVENUE‐SHARING RULE FOR INTERCONNECTION CHARGES* |
0 |
0 |
0 |
40 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
108 |
The Economics of Citation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
11 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
181 |
The Economics of Curiosity |
0 |
0 |
6 |
74 |
0 |
3 |
25 |
448 |
Trade with enemy: Economic interdependence and stability under anarchy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
8 |
Vicarious Liability Under a Strict Liability Rule |
0 |
1 |
6 |
19 |
0 |
1 |
10 |
38 |
Why do firms sell gift cards although consumers prefer cash to gift cards? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
1 |
3 |
5 |
29 |
Why is parochialism prevalent?: an evolutionary approach |
0 |
0 |
0 |
4 |
1 |
3 |
7 |
26 |
Yes-Men and No-Men: Does Defiance Signal Talent? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
20 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
177 |
‘Guaranteed lowest prices: do they facilitate collusion?’: Revisited |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
Total Journal Articles |
5 |
14 |
83 |
2,160 |
39 |
96 |
345 |
10,725 |