Working Paper |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Accounting for Adaptation in the Economics of Happiness |
0 |
0 |
0 |
53 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
80 |
Adjusting for Scale-Use Heterogeneity in Self-Reported Well-Being |
0 |
0 |
3 |
16 |
0 |
1 |
14 |
34 |
Aggregating Local Preferences to Guide Marginal Policy Adjustments |
0 |
0 |
0 |
11 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
61 |
Are Technology Improvements Contractionary? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
98 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
644 |
Are Technology Improvements Contractionary? |
1 |
1 |
5 |
766 |
1 |
3 |
18 |
2,789 |
Are technology improvements contractionary? |
0 |
0 |
1 |
238 |
1 |
1 |
5 |
865 |
Are technology improvements contractionary? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
606 |
0 |
1 |
8 |
2,245 |
Beyond Happiness and Satisfaction: Toward Well-Being Indices Based on Stated Preference |
0 |
0 |
1 |
85 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
286 |
Breaking Through the Zero Lower Bound |
0 |
0 |
3 |
87 |
0 |
1 |
8 |
253 |
Can Marginal Rates of Substitution Be Inferred from Happiness Data? Evidence from Residency Choices |
0 |
0 |
0 |
43 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
197 |
Challenges in Constructing a Survey-Based Well-Being Index |
0 |
0 |
1 |
43 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
77 |
Cognitive Economics |
0 |
0 |
1 |
603 |
0 |
0 |
11 |
353 |
Cyclical Productivity with Unobserved Input Variation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
615 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
2,171 |
Diminishing Marginal Utility Revisited |
0 |
1 |
6 |
20 |
0 |
2 |
20 |
28 |
Do Flexible Durable Goods Prices Undermine Sticky Price Models? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
299 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
798 |
Do Flexible Durable Goods Prices Undermine Sticky Price Models? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
189 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
711 |
Do People Seek to Maximize Happiness? Evidence from New Surveys |
0 |
0 |
1 |
100 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
311 |
Empirics on the Origins of Preferences: The Case of College Major and Religiosity |
0 |
0 |
0 |
71 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
248 |
Enabling Deep Negative Rates to Fight Recessions: A Guide |
0 |
0 |
0 |
84 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
207 |
From Happiness Data to Economic Conclusions |
0 |
1 |
4 |
28 |
0 |
2 |
14 |
41 |
Getting the Biggest Bang for the Buck in Fiscal Policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
32 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
82 |
Happiness Before and After an Election: An Analysis Based on a Daily Survey around Japan's 2009 Election |
0 |
0 |
0 |
12 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
62 |
Happiness Dynamics, Reference Dependence, and Motivated Beliefs in U.S. Presidential Elections |
0 |
0 |
16 |
20 |
0 |
0 |
14 |
19 |
Household Finance in General Equilibrium |
0 |
0 |
1 |
34 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
91 |
Imputing Risk Tolerance from Survey Responses |
0 |
0 |
1 |
139 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
535 |
Koizumi Carried the Day: Did the Japanese Election Results Make People Happy and Unhappy? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
17 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
109 |
Labor Market Dynamics When Unemployment Is A Worker Discipline Device |
0 |
0 |
1 |
74 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
263 |
Labor Supply: Are the Income and Substitution Effects Both Large or Both Small? |
1 |
2 |
5 |
349 |
3 |
6 |
24 |
1,688 |
Liquidity Constraints and Precautionary Saving |
0 |
0 |
1 |
275 |
1 |
2 |
4 |
942 |
Liquidity Constraints and Precautionary Saving |
0 |
0 |
1 |
307 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
928 |
Monetary Policy and Durable Goods |
0 |
0 |
1 |
45 |
1 |
3 |
11 |
85 |
Monetary Policy and Durable Goods |
0 |
0 |
0 |
115 |
3 |
5 |
9 |
250 |
Monetary Policy and Durable Goods |
0 |
0 |
1 |
112 |
0 |
1 |
2 |
188 |
New Methods in the Classical Economics of Uncertainty: Comparing Risks |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
1,218 |
On the Concavity of the Consumption Function |
1 |
1 |
6 |
973 |
4 |
4 |
17 |
4,091 |
On the concavity of the consumption function |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
767 |
Optimal Advice for Monetary Policy |
0 |
0 |
0 |
47 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
288 |
Portfolio Rebalancing in General Equilibrium |
0 |
0 |
0 |
15 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
55 |
Precautionary Motives for Holding Assets |
0 |
1 |
5 |
344 |
4 |
8 |
93 |
2,206 |
Precautionary Saving and Consumption Smoothing Across Time and Possibilities |
0 |
0 |
0 |
8 |
2 |
3 |
4 |
52 |
Precautionary Saving and Consumption Smoothing Across Time and Possibilities |
0 |
0 |
0 |
143 |
2 |
2 |
3 |
745 |
Precautionary Saving and Consumption Smoothing Across Time and Possibilities |
0 |
0 |
0 |
166 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
550 |
Precautionary Saving and Consumption Smoothing Across Time and Possibilities |
0 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
43 |
Precautionary Saving and Consumption Smoothing Across Time and Possibilities |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
Precautionary Saving and Consumption Smoothing Across Time and Possibilities |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
Precautionary Saving and Consumption Smoothing across Time and Possibilities |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
5 |
Precautionary Saving and Consumption Smoothing across Time and Possibilities |
0 |
0 |
0 |
10 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
131 |
Precautionary Saving and Precautionary Wealth |
1 |
1 |
5 |
373 |
1 |
3 |
11 |
742 |
Precautionary Saving and Precautionary Wealth |
0 |
0 |
1 |
61 |
0 |
2 |
8 |
175 |
Precautionary Saving and the Marginal Propensity to Consume |
0 |
0 |
4 |
644 |
1 |
2 |
20 |
2,860 |
Precautionary Saving and the Timing of Taxes |
0 |
0 |
1 |
13 |
1 |
1 |
28 |
156 |
Precautionary Saving and the Timing of Taxes |
0 |
0 |
0 |
80 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
326 |
Precautionary Saving in the Small and in the Large |
0 |
0 |
3 |
366 |
1 |
3 |
13 |
1,134 |
Precautionary Savings and Consumption Smoothing Across Time and Possibilities |
0 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
584 |
Precautionary saving and consumption smoothing across time and possibilities |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
116 |
Preference Parameters and Behavioral Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and Retirement Survey |
0 |
2 |
6 |
606 |
3 |
6 |
16 |
1,851 |
Reconsidering Risk Aversion |
0 |
0 |
2 |
39 |
1 |
1 |
9 |
60 |
Reconsidering Risk Aversion |
0 |
0 |
0 |
20 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
198 |
Risk Preferences in the PSID: Individual Imputations and Family Covariation |
0 |
0 |
1 |
67 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
294 |
Self-reported wellbeing indicators are a valuable complement to traditional economic indicators but aren’t yet ready to compete with them |
0 |
0 |
1 |
37 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
38 |
Seniority |
0 |
0 |
0 |
11 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
16 |
Social Security, Retirement and Wealth: Theory and Implications |
0 |
0 |
0 |
92 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
364 |
Standard Risk Aversion |
0 |
1 |
3 |
337 |
0 |
3 |
12 |
1,175 |
Sticky Price Models and Durable Goods |
0 |
0 |
2 |
626 |
1 |
2 |
8 |
1,452 |
Taxation of Labor Income and the Demand For Risky Assets |
0 |
0 |
1 |
64 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
312 |
Taxation of Labor Income and the Demand for Risky Assets |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
30 |
Taxation of labor income and the demand for risky assets |
0 |
0 |
0 |
167 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
826 |
The Decline of Drudgery and the Paradox of Hard Work |
0 |
0 |
0 |
86 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
290 |
The Decline of Drudgery and the Paradox of Hard Work |
0 |
0 |
0 |
13 |
1 |
2 |
3 |
29 |
The Quantitative Analytics of the Basic Neomonetarist Model |
1 |
2 |
13 |
809 |
7 |
14 |
49 |
2,416 |
Toward a Systematic Approach to the Economic Effects of Risk: Characterizing Utility Functions" |
0 |
0 |
0 |
28 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
57 |
Toward a Systematic Approach to the Economic Effects of Risk: Characterizing Utility Functions" |
0 |
0 |
0 |
19 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
33 |
Unhappiness after Hurricane Katrina |
0 |
2 |
2 |
72 |
1 |
3 |
5 |
460 |
Utility and Happiness |
0 |
0 |
3 |
34 |
1 |
1 |
14 |
42 |
What Do Happiness Data Mean? Theory and Survey Evidence |
0 |
0 |
1 |
35 |
0 |
2 |
6 |
64 |
What Do Happiness Data Mean? Theory and Survey Evidence |
0 |
0 |
0 |
45 |
0 |
0 |
3 |
83 |
What do Happiness Data Mean? Theory and Survey Evidence |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
3 |
What do Happiness Data Mean? Theory and Survey Evidence |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
Total Working Papers |
5 |
15 |
114 |
12,045 |
49 |
105 |
556 |
43,984 |
Journal Article |
File Downloads |
Abstract Views |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
Last month |
3 months |
12 months |
Total |
A Well-Being Snapshot in a Changing World |
0 |
1 |
2 |
27 |
1 |
5 |
6 |
98 |
Aggregating Local Preferences to Guide Marginal Policy Adjustments |
0 |
0 |
0 |
11 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
179 |
Are Technology Improvements Contractionary? |
0 |
1 |
5 |
689 |
2 |
5 |
24 |
2,079 |
Beyond Happiness and Satisfaction: Toward Well-Being Indices Based on Stated Preference |
0 |
2 |
4 |
85 |
1 |
3 |
7 |
492 |
Can Marginal Rates of Substitution Be Inferred from Happiness Data? Evidence from Residency Choices |
0 |
0 |
0 |
17 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
346 |
Challenges in Constructing a Survey-Based Well-Being Index |
0 |
0 |
1 |
26 |
0 |
1 |
3 |
205 |
Cognitive Economics |
0 |
0 |
3 |
24 |
1 |
2 |
10 |
124 |
Farmers' Cooperatives as Behavior Toward Risk |
1 |
1 |
3 |
287 |
1 |
1 |
4 |
783 |
Happiness before and after an election: An analysis based on a daily survey around Japan’s 2009 election |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
1 |
2 |
7 |
104 |
Imputing Risk Tolerance From Survey Responses |
0 |
0 |
0 |
65 |
0 |
1 |
4 |
291 |
Koizumi carried the day: Did the Japanese election results make people happy and unhappy? |
0 |
0 |
0 |
27 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
117 |
Labor-Market Dynamics When Unemployment is a Worker Discipline Device |
0 |
0 |
1 |
89 |
1 |
1 |
3 |
342 |
Liquidity constraints and precautionary saving |
0 |
0 |
7 |
29 |
1 |
2 |
20 |
106 |
Making sense of two-sided altruism |
0 |
1 |
2 |
241 |
0 |
2 |
6 |
475 |
Negative Interest Rate Policy as Conventional Monetary Policy |
0 |
1 |
5 |
235 |
1 |
3 |
12 |
428 |
Negative Interest Rate Policy as Conventional Monetary Policy |
0 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
0 |
1 |
1 |
9 |
New methods in the classical economics of uncertainty: comparing risks |
1 |
1 |
1 |
10 |
3 |
3 |
4 |
64 |
New methods in the classical economics of uncertainty: comparing risks |
0 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
20 |
Next generation monetary policy |
0 |
0 |
1 |
48 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
125 |
On the Concavity of the Consumption Function |
0 |
1 |
5 |
395 |
1 |
3 |
16 |
1,146 |
Portfolio rebalancing in general equilibrium |
0 |
0 |
1 |
14 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
60 |
Precautionary Saving and Consumption Smoothing across Time and Possibilities |
0 |
0 |
0 |
162 |
1 |
2 |
6 |
555 |
Precautionary Saving and Consumption Smoothing across Time and Possibilities |
0 |
1 |
2 |
7 |
1 |
2 |
4 |
22 |
Precautionary Saving and the Timing of Taxes |
0 |
0 |
0 |
100 |
0 |
0 |
2 |
420 |
Precautionary Saving in the Small and in the Large |
0 |
3 |
19 |
1,274 |
2 |
11 |
57 |
3,180 |
Preference Parameters and Behavioral Heterogeneity: An Experimental Approach in the Health and Retirement Study |
2 |
8 |
54 |
393 |
4 |
23 |
151 |
1,999 |
Risk Preferences in the PSID: Individual Imputations and Family Covariation |
0 |
0 |
0 |
118 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
370 |
Self-reported wellbeing indicators are a valuable complement to traditional economic indicators but are not yet ready to compete with them |
0 |
0 |
2 |
11 |
1 |
2 |
6 |
35 |
Standard Risk Aversion |
0 |
1 |
5 |
614 |
1 |
5 |
18 |
2,187 |
Sticky-Price Models and Durable Goods |
0 |
0 |
2 |
399 |
1 |
4 |
6 |
1,133 |
Taxation of Labor Income and the Demand for Risky Assets |
0 |
0 |
0 |
30 |
1 |
1 |
2 |
399 |
The Effect of Uncertainty on Optimal Control Models in the Neighbourhood of a Steady State |
0 |
0 |
0 |
5 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
50 |
The Quantitative Analytics of the Basic Neomonetarist Model |
2 |
3 |
26 |
1,014 |
4 |
9 |
61 |
2,475 |
The effect of demand uncertainty on a precommitted monopoly price |
1 |
1 |
1 |
40 |
1 |
1 |
1 |
135 |
The importance of precautionary motives in explaining individual and aggregate saving: A comment |
0 |
0 |
0 |
21 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
104 |
The quantitative analysis of the basic neomonetarist model |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
1 |
20 |
1,108 |
The relationship between the normalized gradient addition mechanism and quadratic voting |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
0 |
1 |
6 |
70 |
Toward a Systematic Approach to the Economic Effects of Risk: Characterizing Utility Functions |
0 |
0 |
0 |
7 |
0 |
0 |
0 |
41 |
What Do You Think Would Make You Happier? What Do You Think You Would Choose? |
0 |
0 |
7 |
184 |
2 |
7 |
20 |
925 |
What do Happiness Data Mean? Theory and Survey Evidence |
0 |
0 |
4 |
4 |
0 |
5 |
17 |
17 |
Total Journal Articles |
7 |
27 |
165 |
6,722 |
36 |
112 |
517 |
22,818 |